cb_mirror_public:nfib_vs_sebelius_pdf_files_19757

Title: NFIB vs. Sebelius

Original CoS Document (slug): nfib-vs-sebelius

Login Required to view? No

Attached File: nfib-vs-sebelius.pdf

Created: 2023-04-03 10:59:59

Updated: 2024-04-03 23:00:00

Published: 2023-04-03 01:00:00

Converted: 2025-04-14T20:11:29.334929303


background image

(Slip Opinion) 

OCTOBER TERM, 2011 

Syllabus 

NOTE:  Where it is feasible, a syllabus (headnote) will be released, as is

being done in connection with this case, at the time the opinion is issued.

The syllabus constitutes no part of the opinion of the Court but has been

prepared by the Reporter of Decisions for the convenience of the reader. 

See United States v. Detroit Timber & Lumber Co., 200 U. S. 321, 337. 

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES 

Syllabus 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

BUSINESS ET AL. v. SEBELIUS, SECRETARY OF 

HEALTH AND HUMAN SERVICES, ET AL. 

CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR 

THE ELEVENTH CIRCUIT 

No. 11–393.  Argued March 26, 27, 28, 2012—Decided June 28, 2012* 

In 2010, Congress enacted the Patient Protection and Affordable Care

Act in order to increase the number of Americans covered by health 

insurance and decrease the cost of health care.  One key provision is

the individual mandate, which requires most Americans to maintain
“minimum essential” health insurance coverage.  26 U. S. C. §5000A.

For individuals who are not exempt, and who do not receive health

insurance through an employer or government program, the means of
satisfying the requirement is to purchase insurance from a private 

company.  Beginning in 2014, those who do not comply with the 

mandate must make a “[s]hared responsibility payment” to the Fed-
eral Government.  §5000A(b)(1).  The Act provides that this “penalty”

will be paid to the Internal Revenue Service with an individual’s tax-

es, and “shall be assessed and collected in the same manner” as tax 
penalties.  §§5000A©, (g)(1).

Another key provision of the Act is the Medicaid expansion.  The 

current Medicaid program offers federal funding to States to assist 
pregnant women, children, needy families, the blind, the elderly, and 

the disabled in obtaining medical care.  42 U. S. C. §1396d(a).  The 

Affordable Care Act expands the scope of the Medicaid program and
increases the number of individuals the States must cover.  For ex-

—————— 

* Together with No. 11–398, Department of Health and Human Ser-

vices et al. v. Florida et al., and No. 11–400, Florida et al. v. Department 

of Health and Human Services et al., also on certiorari to the same 

court. 

background image

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Syllabus 

ample, the Act requires state programs to provide Medicaid coverage 

by 2014 to adults with incomes up to 133 percent of the federal pov-
erty level, whereas many States now cover adults with children only

if their income is considerably lower, and do not cover childless adults 

at all.  §1396a(a)(10)(A)(i)(VIII).  The Act increases federal funding to
cover the States’ costs in expanding Medicaid coverage.  §1396d(y)(1).

But if a State does not comply with the Act’s new coverage require-

ments, it may lose not only the federal funding for those require-
ments, but all of its federal Medicaid funds.  §1396c. 

Twenty-six States, several individuals, and the National Federa-

tion of Independent Business brought suit in Federal District Court,
challenging the constitutionality of the individual mandate and the

Medicaid expansion.  The Court of Appeals for the Eleventh Circuit 

upheld the Medicaid expansion as a valid exercise of Congress’s 
spending power, but concluded that Congress lacked authority to en-

act the individual mandate.  Finding the mandate severable from the

Act’s other provisions, the Eleventh Circuit left the rest of the Act in-

tact. 

Held: The judgment is affirmed in part and reversed in part. 
648 F. 3d 1235, affirmed in part and reversed in part. 

1. 

CHIEF  JUSTICE  ROBERTS  delivered the opinion of the Court with 

respect to Part II, concluding that the Anti-Injunction Act does not

bar this suit. 

The Anti-Injunction Act provides that “no suit for the purpose of 

restraining the assessment or collection of any tax shall be main-

tained in any court by any person,” 26 U. S. C. §7421(a), so that those

subject to a tax must first pay it and then sue for a refund.  The pre-
sent challenge seeks to restrain the collection of the shared responsi-

bility payment from those who do not comply with the individual

mandate.  But Congress did not intend the payment to be treated as
a “tax” for purposes of the Anti-Injunction Act.  The Affordable Care 

Act describes the payment as a “penalty,” not a “tax.”  That label 

cannot control whether the payment is a tax for purposes of the Con-
stitution, but it does determine the application of the Anti-Injunction 

Act.  The Anti-Injunction Act therefore does not bar this suit.  Pp. 11–

15.
 2. 

CHIEF  JUSTICE  ROBERTS concluded in Part III–A that the indi-

vidual mandate is not a valid exercise of Congress’s power under the 

Commerce Clause and the Necessary and Proper Clause.  Pp. 16–30.

(a) The Constitution grants Congress the power to “regulate 

Commerce.”  Art. I, §8, cl. 3 (emphasis added).  The power to regulate

commerce presupposes the existence of commercial activity to be reg-
ulated.  This Court’s precedent reflects this understanding: As ex-

pansive as this Court’s cases construing the scope of the commerce 

background image

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Syllabus 

power have been, they uniformly describe the power as reaching “ac-

tivity.”  E.g., United States v. Lopez, 514 U. S. 549, 560.  The individ-
ual mandate, however, does not regulate existing commercial activi-

ty.  It instead compels individuals to become active in commerce by

purchasing a product, on the ground that their failure to do so affects
interstate commerce. 

Construing the Commerce Clause to permit Congress to regulate 

individuals precisely because  they are doing nothing would open a 
new and potentially vast domain to congressional authority.  Con-

gress already possesses expansive power to regulate what people do. 

Upholding the Affordable Care Act under the Commerce Clause
would give Congress the same license to regulate what people do not

do.  The Framers knew the difference between doing something and 

doing nothing.  They gave Congress the power to regulate commerce, 
not to compel it.  Ignoring that distinction would undermine the prin-

ciple that the Federal Government is a government of limited and
enumerated powers.  The individual mandate thus cannot be sus-

tained under Congress’s power to “regulate Commerce.”  Pp. 16–27.

(b) Nor can the individual mandate be sustained under the Nec-

essary and Proper Clause as an integral part of the Affordable Care
Act’s other reforms.  Each of this Court’s prior cases upholding laws

under that Clause involved exercises of authority derivative of, and

in service to, a granted power.  E.g., United States v. Comstock, 560 
U. S. ___.  The individual mandate, by contrast, vests Congress with

the extraordinary ability to create the necessary predicate to the ex-

ercise of an enumerated power and draw within its regulatory scope 
those who would otherwise be outside of it.  Even if the individual 

mandate is “necessary” to the Affordable Care Act’s other reforms, 

such an expansion of federal power is not a “proper” means for mak-
ing those reforms effective.  Pp. 27–30. 

3. 

CHIEF JUSTICE ROBERTS concluded in Part III–B that the individ-

ual mandate must be construed as imposing a tax on those who do 
not have health insurance, if such a construction is reasonable. 

The most straightforward reading of the individual mandate is that

it commands individuals to purchase insurance.  But, for the reasons 
explained, the Commerce Clause does not give Congress that power.

It is therefore necessary to turn to the Government’s alternative ar-

gument: that the mandate may be upheld as within Congress’s power 
to “lay and collect Taxes.”  Art. I, §8, cl. 1.  In pressing its taxing

power argument, the Government asks the Court to view the man-

date as imposing a tax on those who do not buy that product.  Be-
cause “every reasonable construction must be resorted to, in order to

save a statute from unconstitutionality,” Hooper v. California, 155 

U. S. 648, 657, the question is whether it is “fairly possible” to inter-

background image

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Syllabus 

pret the mandate as imposing such a tax, Crowell v. Benson, 285 

U. S. 22, 62.  Pp. 31–32. 

4. 

CHIEF  JUSTICE  ROBERTS  delivered the opinion of the Court with 

respect to Part III–C, concluding that the individual mandate may be

upheld as within Congress’s power under the Taxing Clause.  Pp. 33– 
44. 

(a) The Affordable Care Act describes the “[s]hared responsibility

payment” as a “penalty,” not a “tax.”  That label is fatal to the appli-
cation of the Anti-Injunction Act.  It does not, however, control 

whether an exaction is within Congress’s power to tax.  In answering 

that constitutional question, this Court follows a functional approach,
“[d]isregarding the designation of the exaction, and viewing its sub-

stance and application.”  United States v. Constantine, 296 U. S. 287, 

294.  Pp. 33–35. 

(b) Such an analysis suggests that the shared responsibility

payment may for constitutional purposes be considered a tax.  The 

payment is not so high that there is really no choice but to buy health
insurance; the payment is not limited to willful violations, as penal-

ties for unlawful acts often are; and the payment is collected solely by 

the IRS through the normal means of taxation.  Cf. Bailey v. Drexel 
Furniture Co.
, 259 U. S. 20, 36–37.  None of this is to say that pay-

ment is not intended to induce the purchase of health insurance.  But 

the mandate need not be read to declare that failing to do so is un-
lawful.  Neither the Affordable Care Act nor any other law attaches 

negative legal consequences to not buying health insurance, beyond 

requiring a payment to the IRS.  And Congress’s choice of language—
stating that individuals “shall” obtain insurance or pay a “penalty”—

does not require reading §5000A as punishing unlawful conduct.  It 

may also be read as imposing a tax on those who go without insur-
ance.  See New York v. United States, 505 U. S. 144, 169–174. 

Pp. 35–40. 

© Even if the mandate may reasonably be characterized as a

tax, it must still comply with the Direct Tax Clause, which provides:

“No Capitation, or other direct, Tax shall be laid, unless in Proportion 

to the Census or Enumeration herein before directed to be taken.” 
Art. I, §9, cl. 4.  A tax on going without health insurance is not like a

capitation or other direct tax under this Court’s precedents.  It there-

fore need not be apportioned so that each State pays in proportion to
its population.  Pp. 40–41.

5. 

CHIEF  JUSTICE  ROBERTS, joined by JUSTICE  BREYER and JUSTICE 

KAGAN, concluded in Part IV that the Medicaid expansion violates 
the Constitution by threatening States with the loss of their existing 

Medicaid funding if they decline to comply with the expansion. 

Pp. 45–58. 

background image

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Syllabus 

(a) The Spending Clause grants Congress the power “to pay the

Debts and provide for the . . . general Welfare of the United States.” 
Art. I, §8, cl. 1.  Congress may use this power to establish cooperative 

state-federal Spending Clause programs.  The legitimacy of Spending

Clause legislation, however, depends on whether a State voluntarily 
and knowingly accepts the terms of such programs.  Pennhurst State 

School and Hospital v. Halderman, 451 U. S. 1, 17.  “[T]he Constitu-

tion simply does not give Congress the authority to require the States 
to regulate.”  New York v. United States, 505 U. S. 144, 178.  When 

Congress threatens to terminate other grants as a means of pressur-

ing the States to accept a Spending Clause program, the legislation
runs counter to this Nation’s system of federalism.  Cf. South Dakota 

v. Dole, 483 U. S. 203, 211.  Pp. 45–51. 

(b) Section 1396c gives the Secretary of Health and Human Ser-

vices the authority to penalize States that choose not to participate in

the Medicaid expansion by taking away their existing Medicaid fund-
ing.  42 U. S. C. §1396c.  The threatened loss of over 10 percent of a 

State’s overall budget is economic dragooning that leaves the States

with no real option but to acquiesce in the Medicaid expansion.  The 

Government claims that the expansion is properly viewed as only a 
modification of the existing program, and that this modification is

permissible because Congress reserved the “right to alter, amend, or

repeal any provision” of Medicaid.  §1304.  But the expansion accom-
plishes a shift in kind, not merely degree.  The original program was

designed to cover medical services for particular categories of vulner-

able individuals.  Under the Affordable Care Act, Medicaid is trans-
formed into a program to meet the health care needs of the entire

nonelderly population with income below 133 percent of the poverty

level.  A State could hardly anticipate that Congress’s reservation of 
the right to “alter” or “amend” the Medicaid program included the 

power to transform it so dramatically.  The Medicaid expansion thus

violates the Constitution by threatening States with the loss of their
existing Medicaid funding if they decline to comply with the expan-

sion.  Pp. 51–55. 

© 

The constitutional violation is fully remedied by precluding 

the Secretary from applying §1396c to withdraw existing Medicaid

funds for failure to comply with the requirements set out in the ex-

pansion.  See §1303.  The other provisions of the Affordable Care Act 
are not affected.  Congress would have wanted the rest of the Act to 

stand, had it known that States would have a genuine choice whether

to participate in the Medicaid expansion.  Pp. 55–58. 

6. 

JUSTICE GINSBURG, joined by JUSTICE SOTOMAYOR, is of the view 

that the Spending Clause does not preclude the Secretary from with-

holding Medicaid funds based on a State’s refusal to comply with the 

background image

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Syllabus 

expanded Medicaid program.  But given the majority view, she 

agrees with THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE’s  conclusion  in  Part  IV–B  that  the  
Medicaid Act’s severability clause, 42 U. S. C. §1303, determines the

appropriate remedy.  Because THE CHIEF JUSTICE finds the withhold-

ing—not the granting—of federal funds incompatible with the Spend-
ing Clause, Congress’ extension of Medicaid remains available to any 

State that affirms its willingness to participate.  Even absent §1303’s

command, the Court would have no warrant to invalidate the funding
offered by the Medicaid expansion, and surely no basis to tear down

the ACA in its entirety.  When a court confronts an unconstitutional 

statute, its endeavor must be to conserve, not destroy, the legislation. 
See,  e.g.,  Ayotte v. Planned Parenthood of Northern New Eng., 546 

U. S. 320, 328–330.  Pp. 60–61.

 ROBERTS, C. J., announced the judgment of the Court and delivered 

the opinion of the Court with respect to Parts I, II, and III–C, in which 

GINSBURG, BREYER, SOTOMAYOR, and KAGAN, JJ., joined; an opinion with

respect to Part IV, in which BREYER  and KAGAN,  JJ., joined; and an 
opinion with respect to Parts III–A, III–B, and III–D.  GINSBURG, J., 

filed an opinion concurring in part, concurring in the judgment in part,

and dissenting in part, in which SOTOMAYOR, J., joined, and in which
BREYER and KAGAN, JJ., joined as to Parts I, II, III, and IV.  SCALIA, 

KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., filed a dissenting opinion.  THOMAS, 

J., filed a dissenting opinion. 

background image _________________ 

_________________ 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

NOTICE:  This opinion is subject to formal revision before publication in the

preliminary print of the United States Reports.  Readers are requested to

notify the Reporter of Decisions, Supreme Court of the United States, Wash-

ington, D. C. 20543, of any typographical or other formal errors, in order

that corrections may be made before the preliminary print goes to press. 

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES 

Nos. 11–393, 11–398 and 11–400 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

BUSINESS, ET AL., PETITIONERS 

11–393 

v. 

KATHLEEN SEBELIUS, SECRETARY OF HEALTH 

AND HUMAN SERVICES, ET AL. 

DEPARTMENT OF HEALTH AND HUMAN 

SERVICES, ET AL., PETITIONERS 

11–398 

v. 

FLORIDA ET AL. 

FLORIDA, ET AL., PETITIONERS 

11–400 

v. 

DEPARTMENT OF HEALTH AND 

HUMAN SERVICES ET AL. 

ON WRITS OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF 

APPEALS FOR THE ELEVENTH CIRCUIT 

[June 28, 2012] 

CHIEF JUSTICE ROBERTS announced the judgment of the

Court and delivered the opinion of the Court with respect 
to Parts I, II, and III–C, an opinion with respect to Part 
IV, in which JUSTICE  BREYER and JUSTICE  KAGAN join, 
and an opinion with respect to Parts III–A, III–B, and 
III–D. 

Today we resolve constitutional challenges to two provi-

sions of the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act of 

background image

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

2010: the individual mandate, which requires individuals 
to purchase a health insurance policy providing a mini-
mum level of coverage; and the Medicaid expansion, which 
gives funds to the States on the condition that they pro-
vide specified health care to all citizens whose income falls 
below a certain threshold.  We do not consider whether the 
Act embodies sound policies.  That judgment is entrusted 
to the Nation’s elected leaders.  We ask only whether 
Congress has the power under the Constitution to enact
the challenged provisions. 

In our federal system, the National Government pos-

sesses only limited powers; the States and the people
retain the remainder.  Nearly two centuries ago, Chief 
Justice Marshall observed that “the question respecting
the extent of the powers actually granted” to the Federal 
Government “is perpetually arising, and will probably 
continue to arise, as long as our system shall exist.” 
McCulloch v. Maryland, 4 Wheat. 316, 405 (1819).  In this 
case we must again determine whether the Constitution 
grants Congress powers it now asserts, but which many
States and individuals believe it does not possess.  Resolv-
ing this controversy requires us to examine both the limits 
of the Government’s power, and our own limited role in
policing those boundaries.

The Federal Government “is acknowledged by all to 

be one of enumerated powers.”  Ibid.  That is, rather 
than granting general authority to perform all the conceiv-
able functions of government, the Constitution lists, or
enumerates, the Federal Government’s powers.  Congress
may, for example, “coin Money,” “establish Post Offices,”
and “raise and support Armies.”  Art. I, §8, cls. 5, 7, 12. 
The enumeration of powers is also a limitation of pow-
ers, because “[t]he enumeration presupposes something not 
enumerated.”  Gibbons v. Ogden, 9 Wheat. 1, 195 (1824).
The Constitution’s express conferral of some powers
makes clear that it does not grant others.  And the Federal 

background image

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

Government “can exercise only the powers granted to it.” 
McCullochsupra, at 405. 

Today, the restrictions on government power foremost in 

many Americans’ minds are likely to be affirmative pro-
hibitions, such as contained in the Bill of Rights.  These 
affirmative prohibitions come into play, however, only where
the Government possesses authority to act in the first
place.  If no enumerated power authorizes Congress to
pass a certain law, that law may not be enacted, even if it 
would not violate any of the express prohibitions in the 
Bill of Rights or elsewhere in the Constitution.

Indeed, the Constitution did not initially include a Bill 

of Rights at least partly because the Framers felt the enu-
meration of powers sufficed to restrain the Government.
As Alexander Hamilton put it, “the Constitution is itself,
in every rational sense, and to every useful purpose, 
A BILL OF RIGHTS

.”  The Federalist No. 84, p. 515 (C. Ros-

siter ed. 1961).  And when the Bill of Rights was ratified, 
it made express what the enumeration of powers neces-
sarily implied: “The powers not delegated to the United 
States by the Constitution . . . are reserved to the States
respectively, or to the people.”  U. S. Const., Amdt. 10. 
The Federal Government has expanded dramatically over
the past two centuries, but it still must show that a consti-
tutional grant of power authorizes each of its actions.  See, 
e.g., United States v. Comstock, 560 U. S. ___ (2010). 

The same does not apply to the States, because the Con-

stitution is not the source of their power.  The Consti-
tution may restrict state governments—as it does, for 
example, by forbidding them to deny any person the equal 
protection of the laws.  But where such prohibitions do 
not apply, state governments do not need constitutional au-
thorization to act.  The States thus can and do perform
many of the vital functions of modern government—
punishing street crime, running public schools, and zoning 
property for development, to name but a few—even though 

background image

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

the Constitution’s text does not authorize any government
to do so.  Our cases refer to this general power of govern-
ing, possessed by the States but not by the Federal Gov-
ernment, as the “police power.”  See, e.g., United States v. 
Morrison, 529 U. S. 598, 618–619 (2000). 

“State sovereignty is not just an end in itself: Rather,

federalism secures to citizens the liberties that derive from 
the diffusion of sovereign power.”  New York v. United 
States
, 505 U. S. 144, 181 (1992) (internal quotation
marks omitted).  Because the police power is controlled by
50 different States instead of one national sovereign, the 
facets of governing that touch on citizens’ daily lives are 
normally administered by smaller governments closer to
the governed.  The Framers thus ensured that powers 
which “in the ordinary course of affairs, concern the lives,
liberties, and properties of the people” were held by gov-
ernments more local and more accountable than a dis- 
tant federal bureaucracy.  The Federalist No. 45, at 293 
(J. Madison).  The independent power of the States also 
serves as a check on the power of the Federal Government: 
“By denying any one government complete jurisdiction 
over all the concerns of public life, federalism protects the
liberty of the individual from arbitrary power.”  Bond v. 
United States, 564 U. S. ___, ___ (2011) (slip op., at 9–10). 

This case concerns two powers that the Constitution 

does grant the Federal Government, but which must be
read carefully to avoid creating a general federal authority 
akin to the police power.  The Constitution authorizes 
Congress to “regulate Commerce with foreign Nations, and
among the several States, and with the Indian Tribes.”
Art. I, §8, cl. 3.  Our precedents read that to mean that 
Congress may regulate “the channels of interstate com-
merce,” “persons or things in interstate commerce,” and 
“those activities that substantially affect interstate com-
merce.”  Morrisonsupra, at 609 (internal quotation marks
omitted).  The power over activities that substantially 

background image

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

affect interstate commerce can be expansive.  That power
has been held to authorize federal regulation of such seem-
ingly local matters as a farmer’s decision to grow wheat
for himself and his livestock, and a loan shark’s extor-
tionate collections from a neighborhood butcher shop. 
See  Wickard v. Filburn, 317 U. S. 111 (1942); Perez v. 
United States, 402 U. S. 146 (1971).

Congress may also “lay and collect Taxes, Duties, Im-

posts and Excises, to pay the Debts and provide for the
common Defence and general Welfare of the United 
States.”  U. S. Const., Art. I, §8, cl. 1.  Put simply, Con-
gress may tax and spend.  This grant gives the Federal
Government considerable influence even in areas where 
it cannot directly regulate.  The Federal Government may 
enact a tax on an activity that it cannot authorize, forbid,
or otherwise control.  See, e.g., License Tax Cases, 5 Wall. 
462, 471 (1867).  And in exercising its spending power,
Congress may offer funds to the States, and may condition 
those offers on compliance with specified conditions.  See, 
e.g., College Savings Bank v. Florida Prepaid Postsecond-
ary Ed. Expense Bd.
, 527 U. S. 666, 686 (1999).  These 
offers may well induce the States to adopt policies that
the Federal Government itself could not impose.  See, e.g., 
South Dakota
 v. Dole, 483 U. S. 203, 205–206 (1987) (con-
ditioning federal highway funds on States raising their 
drinking age to 21).

The reach of the Federal Government’s enumerated 

powers is broader still because the Constitution authorizes 
Congress to “make all Laws which shall be necessary and
proper for carrying into Execution the foregoing Powers.”
Art. I, §8, cl. 18.  We have long read this provision to give
Congress great latitude in exercising its powers: “Let the
end be legitimate, let it be within the scope of the constitu-
tion, and all means which are appropriate, which are 
plainly adapted to that end, which are not prohibited, but 
consist with the letter and spirit of the constitution, are 

background image

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

constitutional.”  McCulloch, 4 Wheat., at 421. 

Our permissive reading of these powers is explained in

part by a general reticence to invalidate the acts of the
Nation’s elected leaders.  “Proper respect for a co-ordinate 
branch of the government” requires that we strike down
an Act of Congress only if “the lack of constitutional
authority to pass [the] act in question is clearly demon-
strated.”  United States v. Harris, 106 U. S. 629, 635 (1883).
Members of this Court are vested with the authority to
interpret the law; we possess neither the expertise nor
the prerogative to make policy judgments.  Those decisions 
are entrusted to our Nation’s elected leaders, who can be 
thrown out of office if the people disagree with them.  It is 
not our job to protect the people from the consequences of
their political choices.

Our deference in matters of policy cannot, however,

become abdication in matters of law.  “The powers of the 
legislature are defined and limited; and that those lim- 
its may not be mistaken, or forgotten, the constitution is 
written.”  Marbury v. Madison, 1 Cranch 137, 176 (1803). 
Our respect for Congress’s policy judgments thus can 
never extend so far as to disavow restraints on federal 
power that the Constitution carefully constructed.  “The 
peculiar circumstances of the moment may render a 
measure more or less wise, but cannot render it more or 
less constitutional.”  Chief Justice John Marshall, A 
Friend of the Constitution No. V, Alexandria Gazette, July
5, 1819, in John Marshall’s Defense of McCulloch v. Mary-
land
 190–191 (G. Gunther ed. 1969).  And there can be no 
question that it is the responsibility of this Court to en-
force the limits on federal power by striking down acts of
Congress that transgress those limits.  Marbury v. Madi-
son
supra, at 175–176. 

The questions before us must be considered against the

background of these basic principles. 

background image

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of the Court 

In 2010, Congress enacted the Patient Protection and 

Affordable Care Act, 124 Stat. 119.  The Act aims to in-
crease the number of Americans covered by health in-
surance and decrease the cost of health care.  The Act’s 10 
titles stretch over 900 pages and contain hundreds of 
provisions.  This case concerns constitutional challenges to
two key provisions, commonly referred to as the individual 
mandate and the Medicaid expansion.

The individual mandate requires most Americans to

maintain “minimum essential” health insurance coverage.
26 U. S. C. §5000A.  The mandate does not apply to some 
individuals, such as prisoners and undocumented aliens.
§5000A(d).  Many individuals will receive the required cov-
erage through their employer, or from a government pro-
gram such as Medicaid or Medicare.  See §5000A(f).  But 
for individuals who are not exempt and do not receive 
health insurance through a third party, the means of 
satisfying the requirement is to purchase insurance from a 
private company.

Beginning in 2014, those who do not comply with the

mandate must make a “[s]hared responsibility payment” 
to the Federal Government.  §5000A(b)(1).  That payment,
which the Act describes as a “penalty,” is calculated as a 
percentage of household income, subject to a floor based on
a specified dollar amount and a ceiling based on the aver-
age annual premium the individual would have to pay for 
qualifying private health insurance.  §5000A©.  In 2016, 
for example, the penalty will be 2.5 percent of an individ-
ual’s household income, but no less than $695 and no more 
than the average yearly premium for insurance that co-
vers 60 percent of the cost of 10 specified services (e.g., 
prescription drugs and hospitalization).  Ibid.; 42 U. S. C. 
§18022.  The Act provides that the penalty will be paid to
the Internal Revenue Service with an individual’s taxes, 
and “shall be assessed and collected in the same manner” 

background image

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of the Court 

as tax penalties, such as the penalty for claiming too 
large an income tax refund.  26 U. S. C. §5000A(g)(1).  The 
Act, however, bars the IRS from using several of its nor-
mal enforcement tools, such as criminal prosecutions and 
levies.  §5000A(g)(2).  And some individuals who are sub-
ject to the mandate are nonetheless exempt from the 
penalty—for example, those with income below a certain
threshold and members of Indian tribes.  §5000A(e). 

On the day the President signed the Act into law, Flor-

ida and 12 other States filed a complaint in the Federal 
District Court for the Northern District of Florida.  Those 
plaintiffs—who are both respondents and petitioners here,
depending on the issue—were subsequently joined by 13
more States, several individuals, and the National Fed-
eration of Independent Business.  The plaintiffs alleged,
among other things, that the individual mandate provi-
sions of the Act exceeded Congress’s powers under Article 
I of the Constitution.  The District Court agreed, holding
that Congress lacked constitutional power to enact the
individual mandate.  780 F. Supp. 2d 1256 (ND Fla. 2011).
The District Court determined that the individual man-
date could not be severed from the remainder of the Act, 
and therefore struck down the Act in its entirety.  Id., at 
1305–1306. 

The Court of Appeals for the Eleventh Circuit affirmed

in part and reversed in part.  The court affirmed the Dis-
trict Court’s holding that the individual mandate exceeds
Congress’s power.  648 F. 3d 1235 (2011).  The panel
unanimously agreed that the individual mandate did not 
impose a tax, and thus could not be authorized by Con-
gress’s power to “lay and collect Taxes.”  U. S. Const., 
Art. I, §8, cl. 1.  A majority also held that the individual
mandate was not supported by Congress’s power to “regu-
late Commerce . . . among the several States.”  Id.,  cl. 3. 
According to the majority, the Commerce Clause does not 
empower the Federal Government to order individuals to 

background image

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of the Court 

engage in commerce, and the Government’s efforts to cast
the individual mandate in a different light were unpersua-
sive.  Judge Marcus dissented, reasoning that the individ-
ual mandate regulates economic activity that has a clear
effect on interstate commerce. 

Having held the individual mandate to be unconstitu-

tional, the majority examined whether that provision 
could be severed from the remainder of the Act.  The ma-
jority determined that, contrary to the District Court’s 
view, it could.  The court thus struck down only the indi-
vidual mandate, leaving the Act’s other provisions intact.
648 F. 3d, at 1328. 

Other Courts of Appeals have also heard challenges to 

the individual mandate.  The Sixth Circuit and the D. C. 
Circuit upheld the mandate as a valid exercise of Con-
gress’s commerce power.  See Thomas More Law Center v. 
Obama, 651 F. 3d 529 (CA6 2011); Seven-Sky v. Holder
661 F. 3d 1 (CADC 2011).  The Fourth Circuit determined 
that the Anti-Injunction Act prevents courts from consid-
ering the merits of that question.  See Liberty Univ., Inc. 
v. Geithner, 671 F. 3d 391 (2011).  That statute bars suits 
“for the purpose of restraining the assessment or collection 
of any tax.”  26 U. S. C. §7421(a).  A majority of the Fourth 
Circuit panel reasoned that the individual mandate’s
penalty is a tax within the meaning of the Anti-Injunction 
Act, because it is a financial assessment collected by the 
IRS through the normal means of taxation.  The majority
therefore determined that the plaintiffs could not chal-
lenge the individual mandate until after they paid the
penalty.1 
—————— 

1

The Eleventh Circuit did not consider whether the Anti-Injunction 

Act bars challenges to the individual mandate.  The District Court had 

determined that it did not, and neither side challenged that holding on 
appeal.  The same was true in the Fourth Circuit, but that court 

examined the question sua sponte because it viewed the Anti-Injunction

Act as a limit on its subject matter jurisdiction.  See Liberty Univ., 671 

background image 10 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of the Court 

The second provision of the Affordable Care Act directly

challenged here is the Medicaid expansion.  Enacted in 
1965, Medicaid offers federal funding to States to assist 
pregnant women, children, needy families, the blind, the 
elderly, and the disabled in obtaining medical care.  See 42 
U. S. C. §1396a(a)(10).  In order to receive that funding,
States must comply with federal criteria governing mat-
ters such as who receives care and what services are pro-
vided at what cost.  By 1982 every State had chosen to
participate in Medicaid.  Federal funds received through 
the Medicaid program have become a substantial part of
state budgets, now constituting over 10 percent of most 
States’ total revenue. 

The Affordable Care Act expands the scope of the Medi-

caid program and increases the number of individuals the 
States must cover.  For example, the Act requires state 
programs to provide Medicaid coverage to adults with
incomes up to 133 percent of the federal poverty level, 
whereas many States now cover adults with children only 
if their income is considerably lower, and do not cover 
childless adults at all.  See §1396a(a)(10)(A)(i)(VIII).  The 
Act increases federal funding to cover the States’ costs in 
expanding Medicaid coverage, although States will bear a 
portion of the costs on their own.  §1396d(y)(1).  If a State 
does not comply with the Act’s new coverage require-
ments, it may lose not only the federal funding for those
requirements, but all of its federal Medicaid funds.  See 
§1396c.

Along with their challenge to the individual mandate,

the state plaintiffs in the Eleventh Circuit argued that the 
Medicaid expansion exceeds Congress’s constitutional 

—————— 
F. 3d, at 400–401.  The Sixth Circuit and the D. C. Circuit considered 
the question but determined that the Anti-Injunction Act did not apply.

See Thomas More, 651 F. 3d, at 539–540 (CA6); Seven-Sky, 661 F. 3d, 
at 5–14 (CADC). 

background image 11 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of the Court 

powers.  The Court of Appeals unanimously held that the
Medicaid expansion is a valid exercise of Congress’s power 
under the Spending Clause.  U. S. Const., Art. I, §8, cl. 1. 
And the court rejected the States’ claim that the threat-
ened loss of all federal Medicaid funding violates the
Tenth Amendment by coercing them into complying with
the Medicaid expansion.  648 F. 3d, at 1264, 1268. 

We granted certiorari to review the judgment of the

Court of Appeals for the Eleventh Circuit with respect to
both the individual mandate and the Medicaid expansion. 
565 U. S. ___ (2011).  Because no party supports the Elev-
enth Circuit’s holding that the individual mandate can
be completely severed from the remainder of the Affordable
Care Act, we appointed an amicus curiae to defend that 
aspect of the judgment below.  And because there is a 
reasonable argument that the Anti-Injunction Act de-
prives us of jurisdiction to hear challenges to the individ-
ual mandate, but no party supports that proposition, we
appointed an amicus curiae to advance it.2 

II 

Before turning to the merits, we need to be sure we have 

the authority to do so.  The Anti-Injunction Act provides 
that “no suit for the purpose of restraining the assessment
or collection of any tax shall be maintained in any court 
by any person, whether or not such person is the per-
son against whom such tax was assessed.”  26 U. S. C. 
§7421(a).  This statute protects the Government’s ability
to collect a consistent stream of revenue, by barring litiga-
tion to enjoin or otherwise obstruct the collection of taxes. 
Because of the Anti-Injunction Act, taxes can ordinarily be 
—————— 

2

We appointed H. Bartow Farr III to brief and argue in support of the

Eleventh Circuit’s judgment with respect to severability, and Robert A.
Long to brief and argue the proposition that the Anti-Injunction Act 

bars the current challenges to the individual mandate.  565 U. S. ___ 

(2011) Both amici have ably discharged their assigned responsibilities. 

background image 12 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of the Court 

challenged only after they are paid, by suing for a refund.
See Enochs v. Williams Packing & Nav. Co., 370 U. S. 1, 
7–8 (1962).

The penalty for not complying with the Affordable Care

Act’s individual mandate first becomes enforceable in 
2014.  The present challenge to the mandate thus seeks to 
restrain the penalty’s future collection.  Amicus contends 
that the Internal Revenue Code treats the penalty as a
tax, and that the Anti-Injunction Act therefore bars this
suit. 

The text of the pertinent statutes suggests otherwise.

The Anti-Injunction Act applies to suits “for the purpose
of restraining the assessment or collection of any tax.” 
§7421(a) (emphasis added).  Congress, however, chose to
describe the “[s]hared responsibility payment” imposed on
those who forgo health insurance not as a “tax,” but as a
“penalty.”  §§5000A(b), (g)(2).  There is no immediate 
reason to think that a statute applying to “any tax” would
apply to a “penalty.”

Congress’s decision to label this exaction a “penalty”

rather than a “tax” is significant because the Affordable
Care Act describes many other exactions it creates as
“taxes.”  See Thomas More, 651 F. 3d, at 551.  Where 
Congress uses certain language in one part of a statute
and different language in another, it is generally pre-
sumed that Congress acts intentionally.  See Russello v. 
United States, 464 U. S. 16, 23 (1983). 

Amicus argues that even though Congress did not label 

the shared responsibility payment a tax, we should treat it
as such under the Anti-Injunction Act because it functions
like a tax.  It is true that Congress cannot change whether 
an exaction is a tax or a penalty for constitutional pur-
poses simply by describing it as one or the other.  Congress
may not, for example, expand its power under the Taxing
Clause, or escape the Double Jeopardy Clause’s constraint 
on criminal sanctions, by labeling a severe financial pun-

background image  

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

13 

 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

ishment a “tax.”  See Bailey v. Drexel Furniture  Co., 259 
U. S. 20, 36–37 (1922); Department of Revenue of Mont. v. 
Kurth Ranch, 511 U. S. 767, 779 (1994). 
  The Anti-Injunction Act and the Affordable Care Act, 
however, are creatures of Congress’s own creation.  How 
they relate to each other is up to Congress, and the best 
evidence of Congress’s intent is the statutory text.  We 
have thus applied the Anti-Injunction Act to statutorily 
described “taxes” even where that label was inaccurate.  
See Bailey v. George, 259 U. S. 16 (1922) (Anti-Injunction 
Act applies to “Child Labor Tax” struck down as exceeding 
Congress’s taxing power in Drexel Furniture). 
  Congress can, of course, describe something as a penalty 
but direct that it nonetheless be treated as a tax for pur-
poses of the Anti-Injunction Act.  For example, 26 U. S. C. 
§6671(a) provides that “any reference in this title to ‘tax’ 
imposed by this title shall be deemed also to refer to the 
penalties and liabilities provided by” subchapter 68B of 
the Internal Revenue Code.  Penalties in subchapter 68B 
are thus treated as taxes under Title 26, which includes 
the Anti-Injunction Act.  The individual mandate, how-
ever, is not in subchapter 68B of the Code.  Nor does any 
other provision state that references to taxes in Title 26 
shall also be “deemed” to apply to the individual mandate. 
  Amicus attempts to show that Congress did render the 
Anti-Injunction Act applicable to the individual mandate, 
albeit by a more circuitous route.  Section 5000A(g)(1) spec-
ifies that the penalty for not complying with the man- 
date “shall be assessed and collected in the same manner 
as an assessable penalty under subchapter B of chapter 
68.”  Assessable penalties in subchapter 68B, in turn, 
“shall be assessed and collected in the same manner as 
taxes.”  §6671(a).  According to amicus, by directing that 
the penalty be “assessed and collected in the same man-
ner as taxes,” §5000A(g)(1) made the Anti-Injunction Act 
applicable to this penalty. 

Opinion of the Court 

background image 14 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of the Court 

The Government disagrees.  It argues that §5000A(g)(1) 

does not direct courts to apply the Anti-Injunction Act,
because §5000A(g) is a directive only to the Secretary of 
the Treasury to use the same “‘methodology and proce-
dures’ ” to collect the penalty that he uses to collect taxes. 
Brief for United States 32–33 (quoting Seven-Sky, 661 
F. 3d, at 11).

We think the Government has the better reading.  As 

it observes, “Assessment” and “Collection” are chapters of 
the Internal Revenue Code providing the Secretary author-
ity to assess and collect taxes, and generally specifying
the means by which he shall do so.  See §6201 (assess-
ment authority); §6301 (collection authority).  Section 
5000A(g)(1)’s command that the penalty be “assessed and 
collected in the same manner” as taxes is best read as 
referring to those chapters and giving the Secretary the
same authority and guidance with respect to the penalty. 
That interpretation is consistent with the remainder of
§5000A(g), which instructs the Secretary on the tools he
may use to collect the penalty.  See §5000A(g)(2)(A) (bar-
ring criminal prosecutions); §5000A(g)(2)(B) (prohibiting 
the Secretary from using notices of lien and levies).  The 
Anti-Injunction Act, by contrast, says nothing about the 
procedures to be used in assessing and collecting taxes. 

Amicus argues in the alternative that a different section

of the Internal Revenue Code requires courts to treat the 
penalty as a tax under the Anti-Injunction Act.  Section 
6201(a) authorizes the Secretary to make “assessments of 
all taxes (including interest, additional amounts, additions
to the tax, and assessable penalties).”  (Emphasis added.) 
Amicus contends that the penalty must be a tax, because
it is an assessable penalty and §6201(a) says that taxes
include assessable penalties.

That argument has force only if §6201(a) is read in

isolation.  The Code contains many provisions treating
taxes and assessable penalties as distinct terms.  See, e.g., 

background image 15 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

§§860(h)(1), 6324A(a), 6601(e)(1)–(2), 6602, 7122(b).  There 
would, for example, be no need for §6671(a) to deem “tax”
to refer to certain assessable penalties if the Code al-
ready included all such penalties in the term “tax.”  In-
deed,  amicus’s earlier observation that the Code requires
assessable penalties to be assessed and collected “in the
same manner as taxes” makes little sense if assessable 
penalties are themselves taxes.  In light of the Code’s 
consistent distinction between the terms “tax” and “as-
sessable penalty,” we must accept the Government’s in-
terpretation: §6201(a) instructs the Secretary that his 
authority to assess taxes includes the authority to assess
penalties, but it does not equate assessable penalties to
taxes for other purposes.

The Affordable Care Act does not require that the pen-

alty for failing to comply with the individual mandate be
treated as a tax for purposes of the Anti-Injunction Act.
The Anti-Injunction Act therefore does not apply to this
suit, and we may proceed to the merits. 

III 

The Government advances two theories for the proposi-

tion that Congress had constitutional authority to enact 
the individual mandate.  First, the Government argues
that Congress had the power to enact the mandate under 
the Commerce Clause.  Under that theory, Congress may
order individuals to buy health insurance because the
failure to do so affects interstate commerce, and could un-
dercut the Affordable Care Act’s other reforms.  Second, 
the Government argues that if the commerce power does 
not support the mandate, we should nonetheless uphold it
as an exercise of Congress’s power to tax.  According to the 
Government, even if Congress lacks the power to direct
individuals to buy insurance, the only effect of the indi-
vidual mandate is to raise taxes on those who do not do so, 
and thus the law may be upheld as a tax. 

background image 16 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

The Government’s first argument is that the individual 

mandate is a valid exercise of Congress’s power under the 
Commerce Clause and the Necessary and Proper Clause. 
According to the Government, the health care market is
characterized by a significant cost-shifting problem.  Every-
one will eventually need health care at a time and to an 
extent they cannot predict, but if they do not have insur-
ance, they often will not be able to pay for it.  Because 
state and federal laws nonetheless require hospitals to
provide a certain degree of care to individuals without 
regard to their ability to pay, see, e.g., 42 U. S. C. §1395dd; 
Fla. Stat. Ann. §395.1041, hospitals end up receiving 
compensation for only a portion of the services they pro-
vide.  To recoup the losses, hospitals pass on the cost to
insurers through higher rates, and insurers, in turn, pass
on the cost to policy holders in the form of higher pre-
miums.  Congress estimated that the cost of uncompen-
sated care raises family health insurance premiums, on
average, by over $1,000 per year.  42 U. S. C. §18091(2)(F).

In the Affordable Care Act, Congress addressed the

problem of those who cannot obtain insurance coverage
because of preexisting conditions or other health issues.  It 
did so through the Act’s “guaranteed-issue” and “community- 
rating” provisions.  These provisions together prohibit in-
surance companies from denying coverage to those with 
such conditions or charging unhealthy individuals higher 
premiums than healthy individuals.  See §§300gg, 300gg–1, 
300gg–3, 300gg–4

The guaranteed-issue and community-rating reforms do

not, however, address the issue of healthy individuals who
choose not to purchase insurance to cover potential health
care needs.  In fact, the reforms sharply exacerbate that
problem, by providing an incentive for individuals to delay
purchasing health insurance until they become sick, rely-
ing on the promise of guaranteed and affordable coverage. 

background image 17 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

The reforms also threaten to impose massive new costs on 
insurers, who are required to accept unhealthy individuals 
but prohibited from charging them rates necessary to pay
for their coverage.  This will lead insurers to significantly 
increase premiums on everyone.  See Brief for America’s 
Health Insurance Plans et al. as Amici Curiae in No. 11– 
393 etc. 8–9. 

The individual mandate was Congress’s solution to

these problems.  By requiring that individuals purchase
health insurance, the mandate prevents cost-shifting by
those who would otherwise go without it.  In addition, the 
mandate forces into the insurance risk pool more healthy
individuals, whose premiums on average will be higher 
than their health care expenses.  This allows insurers to 
subsidize the costs of covering the unhealthy individuals 
the reforms require them to accept.  The Government 
claims that Congress has power under the Commerce and
Necessary and Proper Clauses to enact this solution. 

The Government contends that the individual mandate 

is within Congress’s power because the failure to pur-
chase insurance “has a substantial and deleterious effect 
on interstate commerce” by creating the cost-shifting prob-
lem.  Brief for United States 34.  The path of our Com-
merce Clause decisions has not always run smooth, see 
United States v. Lopez, 514 U. S. 549, 552–559 (1995), but 
it is now well established that Congress has broad author-
ity under the Clause.  We have recognized, for example, 
that “[t]he power of Congress over interstate commerce is 
not confined to the regulation of commerce among the
states,” but extends to activities that “have a substantial 
effect on interstate commerce.”  United States v.  Darby
312 U. S. 100, 118–119 (1941).  Congress’s power, more-
over, is not limited to regulation of an activity that by itself
substantially affects interstate commerce, but also extends 

background image 18 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

to activities that do so only when aggregated with similar 
activities of others.  See Wickard, 317 U. S., at 127–128. 

Given its expansive scope, it is no surprise that Con-

gress has employed the commerce power in a wide variety 
of ways to address the pressing needs of the time.  But 
Congress has never attempted to rely on that power to
compel individuals not engaged in commerce to purchase
an unwanted product.3  Legislative novelty is not nec-
essarily fatal; there is a first time for everything.  But 
sometimes “the most telling indication of [a] severe con-
stitutional problem . . . is the lack of historical precedent” 
for Congress’s action.  Free Enterprise Fund v. Public Com-
pany Accounting Oversight Bd.
, 561 U. S. ___, ___ (2010) 
(slip op., at 25) (internal quotation marks omitted).  At the 
very least, we should “pause to consider the implications of
the Government’s arguments” when confronted with such 
new conceptions of federal power.  Lopezsupra, at 564. 

The Constitution grants Congress the power to “regulate 

Commerce.”  Art. I, §8, cl. 3 (emphasis added).  The power 
to  regulate  commerce presupposes the existence of com-
mercial activity to be regulated.  If the power to “regulate”
something included the power to create it, many of the
provisions in the Constitution would be superfluous.  For 
example, the Constitution gives Congress the power to
“coin Money,” in addition to the power to “regulate the 
Value thereof.”  Id., cl. 5.  And it gives Congress the power 
—————— 

3

The examples of other congressional mandates cited by JUSTICE 

GINSBURG, post, at 35, n. 10 (opinion concurring in part, concurring in 
judgment in part, and dissenting in part), are not to the contrary.  Each 

of those mandates—to report for jury duty, to register for the draft, to

purchase firearms in anticipation of militia service, to exchange gold
currency for paper currency, and to file a tax return—are based on 

constitutional provisions other than the Commerce Clause.  See Art. I, 

§8, cl. 9 (to “constitute Tribunals inferior to the supreme Court”); id., 
cl. 12 (to “raise and support Armies”); id., cl. 16 (to “provide for organiz-

ing, arming, and disciplining, the Militia”); id., cl. 5 (to “coin Money”); 

id., cl. 1 (to “lay and collect Taxes”). 

background image 19 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

to “raise and support Armies” and to “provide and main-
tain a Navy,” in addition to the power to “make Rules 
for the Government and Regulation of the land and naval
Forces.”  Id., cls. 12–14.  If the power to regulate the 
armed forces or the value of money included the power to 
bring the subject of the regulation into existence, the
specific grant of such powers would have been unneces-
sary.  The language of the Constitution reflects the natu-
ral understanding that the power to regulate assumes
there is already something to be regulated.  See Gibbons, 9 
Wheat., at 188 (“[T]he enlightened patriots who framed 
our constitution, and the people who adopted it, must be 
understood to have employed words in their natural sense, 
and to have intended what they have said”).4 

Our precedent also reflects this understanding.  As 

expansive as our cases construing the scope of the com-
merce power have been, they all have one thing in com-
mon: They uniformly describe the power as reaching 
“activity.”  It is nearly impossible to avoid the word when
quoting them.  See, e.g.,  Lopez,  supra, at 560 (“Where 
economic activity substantially affects interstate com-
merce, legislation regulating that activity will be sus-

—————— 

JUSTICE  GINSBURG suggests that “at the time the Constitution was

framed, to ‘regulate’ meant, among other things, to require action.” 

Post, at 23 (citing Seven-Sky  v.  Holder, 661 F. 3d 1, 16 (CADC 2011); 
brackets and some internal quotation marks omitted).  But to reach 

this conclusion, the case cited by JUSTICE GINSBURG relied on a diction-

ary in which “[t]o order; to command” was the fifth-alternative defini-
tion of “to direct,” which was itself the second-alternative definition of 

“to regulate.”  See Seven-Skysupra, at 16 (citing S. Johnson, Diction-
ary of the English Language (4th ed. 1773) (reprinted 1978)).  It is 

unlikely that the Framers had such an obscure meaning in mind when

they used the word “regulate.”  Far more commonly, “[t]o regulate”

meant “[t]o adjust by rule or method,” which presupposes something to 
adjust.  2 Johnson, supra, at 1619; see also Gibbons, 9 Wheat., at 196 

(defining the commerce power as the power “to prescribe the rule by 
which commerce is to be governed”). 

background image 20 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

tained”);  Perez, 402 U. S., at 154 (“Where the class of 
activities
 is regulated and that class is within the reach of 
federal power, the courts have no power to excise, as triv-
ial, individual instances of the class” (emphasis in original; 
internal quotation marks omitted)); Wickard,  supra, at 
125 (“[E]ven if appellee’s activity be local and though it 
may not be regarded as commerce, it may still, whatever
its nature, be reached by Congress if it exerts a substan-
tial economic effect on interstate commerce”); NLRB  v. 
Jones & Laughlin Steel Corp., 301 U. S. 1, 37 (1937) (“Al-
though activities may be intrastate in character when
separately considered, if they have such a close and sub-
stantial relation to interstate commerce that their control 
is essential or appropriate to protect that commerce from
burdens and obstructions, Congress cannot be denied the
power to exercise that control”); see also post, at 15, 25–26, 
28, 32 (GINSBURG, J., concurring in part, concurring in 
judgment in part, and dissenting in part).5 

The individual mandate, however, does not regulate

existing commercial activity.  It instead compels individ-
uals to become active in commerce by purchasing a product,
on the ground that their failure to do so affects interstate 
commerce.  Construing the Commerce Clause to permit Con-
gress to regulate individuals precisely because  they are
doing nothing would open a new and potentially vast do-
main to congressional authority.  Every day individuals do
not  do an infinite number of things.  In some cases they 
—————— 

JUSTICE GINSBURG cites two eminent domain cases from the 1890s to 

support the proposition that our case law does not “toe the activity

versus inactivity line.”  Post, at 24–25 (citing Monongahela Nav. Co. v. 

United States, 148 U. S. 312, 335–337 (1893), and Cherokee Nation v. 
Southern Kansas R. Co., 135 U. S. 641, 657–659 (1890)).  The fact that 

the Fifth Amendment requires the payment of just compensation
when the Government exercises its power of eminent domain does not 

turn the taking into a commercial transaction between the landowner 

and the Government, let alone a government-compelled transaction
between the landowner and a third party. 

background image 21 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

decide not to do something; in others they simply fail to
do it.  Allowing Congress to justify federal regulation by
pointing to the effect of inaction on commerce would bring
countless decisions an individual could potentially make 
within the scope of federal regulation, and—under the 
Government’s theory—empower Congress to make those
decisions for him. 

Applying the Government’s logic to the familiar case of 

Wickard  v.  Filburn shows how far that logic would carry
us from the notion of a government of limited powers.  In 
Wickard, the Court famously upheld a federal penalty im-
posed on a farmer for growing wheat for consumption 
on his own farm.  317 U. S., at 114–115, 128–129.  That 
amount of wheat caused the farmer to exceed his quota 
under a program designed to support the price of wheat by 
limiting supply.  The Court rejected the farmer’s argument
that growing wheat for home consumption was beyond the 
reach of the commerce power.  It did so on the ground that
the farmer’s decision to grow wheat for his own use al-
lowed him to avoid purchasing wheat in the market.  That 
decision, when considered in the aggregate along with sim-
ilar decisions of others, would have had a substantial ef-
fect on the interstate market for wheat.  Id., at 127–129. 

Wickard  has long been regarded as “perhaps the most 

far reaching example of Commerce Clause authority over 
intrastate activity,” Lopez, 514 U. S., at 560, but the Gov-
ernment’s theory in this case would go much further.
Under  Wickard it is within Congress’s power to regulate 
the market for wheat by supporting its price.  But price 
can be supported by increasing demand as well as by
decreasing supply.  The aggregated decisions of some
consumers not to purchase wheat have a substantial effect 
on the price of wheat, just as decisions not to purchase
health insurance have on the price of insurance.  Congress
can therefore command that those not buying wheat do so,
just as it argues here that it may command that those not 

background image 22 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

buying health insurance do so.  The farmer in Wickard 
was at least actively engaged in the production of wheat, 
and the Government could regulate that activity because 
of its effect on commerce.  The Government’s theory here
would effectively override that limitation, by establishing 
that individuals may be regulated under the Commerce
Clause whenever enough of them are not doing something 
the Government would have them do. 

Indeed, the Government’s logic would justify a manda-

tory purchase to solve almost any problem.  See Seven-Sky
661 F. 3d, at 14–15 (noting the Government’s inability
to “identify any mandate to purchase a product or ser- 
vice in interstate commerce that would be unconstitu-
tional” under its theory of the commerce power).  To 
consider a different example in the health care market, many 
Americans do not eat a balanced diet.  That group makes 
up a larger percentage of the total population than those 
without health insurance.  See, e.g., Dept. of Agriculture 
and Dept. of Health and Human Services, Dietary Guide-
lines for Americans 1 (2010).  The failure of that group 
to have a healthy diet increases health care costs, to a
greater extent than the failure of the uninsured to pur-
chase insurance.  See, e.g., Finkelstein, Trogdon, Cohen, & 
Dietz, Annual Medical Spending Attributable to Obesity: 
Payer- and Service-Specific Estimates, 28 Health Affairs
w822 (2009) (detailing the “undeniable link between ris-
ing rates of obesity and rising medical spending,” and esti-
mating that “the annual medical burden of obesity has
risen to almost 10 percent of all medical spending and 
could amount to $147 billion per year in 2008”).  Those in-
creased costs are borne in part by other Americans who 
must pay more, just as the uninsured shift costs to the 
insured.  See Center for Applied Ethics, Voluntary Health 
Risks: Who Should Pay?, 6 Issues in Ethics 6 (1993) (not-
ing “overwhelming evidence that individuals with un-
healthy habits pay only a fraction of the costs associated 

background image 23 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

with their behaviors; most of the expense is borne by the 
rest of society in the form of higher insurance premiums,
government expenditures for health care, and disability 
benefits”).  Congress addressed the insurance problem by 
ordering everyone to buy insurance.  Under the Gov-
ernment’s theory, Congress could address the diet problem 
by ordering everyone to buy vegetables.  See Dietary
Guidelines, supra, at 19 (“Improved nutrition, appropriate
eating behaviors, and increased physical activity have tre-
mendous potential to . . . reduce health care costs”).

People, for reasons of their own, often fail to do things

that would be good for them or good for society.  Those 
failures—joined with the similar failures of others—can
readily have a substantial effect on interstate commerce. 
Under the Government’s logic, that authorizes Congress to 
use its commerce power to compel citizens to act as the 
Government would have them act. 

That is not the country the Framers of our Constitution

envisioned.  James Madison explained that the Commerce
Clause was “an addition which few oppose and from which
no apprehensions are entertained.”  The Federalist No. 45, 
at 293.  While Congress’s authority under the Commerce 
Clause has of course expanded with the growth of the
national economy, our cases have “always recognized that 
the power to regulate commerce, though broad indeed, has 
limits.”  Maryland v. Wirtz, 392 U. S. 183, 196 (1968).  The 
Government’s theory would erode those limits, permitting 
Congress to reach beyond the natural extent of its author-
ity, “everywhere extending the sphere of its activity and
drawing all power into its impetuous vortex.”  The Feder-
alist No. 48, at 309 (J. Madison).  Congress already enjoys
vast power to regulate much of what we do.  Accepting 
the Government’s theory would give Congress the same
license to regulate what we do not do, fundamentally 
changing the relation between the citizen and the Federal 

background image 24 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

Government.6 

To an economist, perhaps, there is no difference between 

activity and inactivity; both have measurable economic 
effects on commerce.  But the distinction between doing
something and doing nothing would not have been lost on 
the Framers, who were “practical statesmen,” not meta-
physical philosophers.  Industrial Union Dept., AFL–CIO 
v. American Petroleum Institute, 448 U. S. 607, 673 (1980) 
(Rehnquist, J., concurring in judgment).  As we have ex-
plained, “the framers of the Constitution were not mere
visionaries, toying with speculations or theories, but 
practical men, dealing with the facts of political life as 
they understood them, putting into form the government 
they were creating, and prescribing in language clear 
and intelligible the powers that government was to take.” 
South Carolina v. United States, 199 U. S. 437, 449 (1905). 
The Framers gave Congress the power to regulate com-
merce, not to compel it, and for over 200 years both our 
decisions and Congress’s actions have reflected this un-
derstanding.  There is no reason to depart from that un-
derstanding now.

The Government sees things differently.  It argues that

because sickness and injury are unpredictable but una-
voidable, “the uninsured as a class are active in the mar-
ket for health care, which they regularly seek and obtain.”
Brief for United States 50.  The individual mandate 
“merely regulates how individuals finance and pay for that 

—————— 

6

In an attempt to recast the individual mandate as a regulation of 

commercial activity, JUSTICE  GINSBURG suggests that “[a]n individual

who opts not to purchase insurance from a private insurer can be seen 
as actively selecting another form of insurance: self-insurance.”  Post, at 

26.  But “self-insurance” is, in this context, nothing more than a de-

scription of the failure to purchase insurance.  Individuals are no more 
“activ[e] in the self-insurance market” when they fail to purchase 

insurance, ibid., than they are active in the “rest” market when doing 
nothing. 

background image 25 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

active participation—requiring that they do so through
insurance, rather than through attempted self-insurance
with the back-stop of shifting costs to others.”  Ibid. 

The Government repeats the phrase “active in the mar-

ket for health care” throughout its brief, see id., at 7, 18, 
34, 50, but that concept has no constitutional significance.
An individual who bought a car two years ago and may 
buy another in the future is not “active in the car market”
in any pertinent sense.  The phrase “active in the market”
cannot obscure the fact that most of those regulated by
the individual mandate are not currently engaged in any 
commercial activity involving health care, and that fact is
fatal to the Government’s effort to “regulate the uninsured 
as a class.”  Id., at 42.  Our precedents recognize Con-
gress’s power to regulate “class[es] of activities,” Gonzales 
v.  Raich, 545 U. S. 1, 17 (2005) (emphasis added), not 
classes of individuals, apart from any activity in which
they are engaged, see, e.g., Perez, 402 U. S., at 153 (“Peti-
tioner is clearly a member of the class which engages in
‘extortionate credit transactions’ . . .” (emphasis deleted)).

The individual mandate’s regulation of the uninsured as

a class is, in fact, particularly divorced from any link to
existing commercial activity.  The mandate primarily
affects healthy, often young adults who are less likely to
need significant health care and have other priorities for
spending their money.  It is precisely because these indi-
viduals, as an actuarial class, incur relatively low health
care costs that the mandate helps counter the effect of
forcing insurance companies to cover others who impose
greater costs than their premiums are allowed to reflect.
See 42 U. S. C. §18091(2)(I) (recognizing that the mandate
would “broaden the health insurance risk pool to include 
healthy individuals, which will lower health insurance 
premiums”).  If the individual mandate is targeted at a 
class, it is a class whose commercial inactivity rather than
activity is its defining feature. 

background image 26 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

The Government, however, claims that this does not 

matter.  The Government regards it as sufficient to trigger
Congress’s authority that almost all those who are unin-
sured will, at some unknown point in the future, engage
in a health care transaction.  Asserting that “[t]here is no 
temporal limitation in the Commerce Clause,” the Gov-
ernment argues that because “[e]veryone subject to this 
regulation is in or will be in the health care market,” they 
can be “regulated in advance.”  Tr. of Oral Arg. 109 (Mar. 
27, 2012).

The proposition that Congress may dictate the conduct

of an individual today because of prophesied future ac-
tivity finds no support in our precedent.  We have said that 
Congress can anticipate the effects on commerce of an eco-
nomic activity.  See, e.g., Consolidated Edison Co. v. NLRB
305 U. S. 197 (1938) (regulating the labor practices of 
utility companies); Heart of Atlanta Motel, Inc. v.  United 
States
, 379 U. S. 241 (1964) (prohibiting discrimination by
hotel operators); Katzenbach  v.  McClung, 379 U. S. 294 
(1964) (prohibiting discrimination by restaurant owners). 
But we have never permitted Congress to anticipate that 
activity itself in order to regulate individuals not currently
engaged in commerce.  Each one of our cases, including 
those cited by JUSTICE GINSBURG, post, at 20–21, involved 

preexisting economic activity.  See, e.g.,  Wickard, 317 
U. S., at 127–129 (producing wheat); Raich,  supra, at 25 
(growing marijuana).

Everyone will likely participate in the markets for food, 

clothing, transportation, shelter, or energy; that does not 
authorize Congress to direct them to purchase particular 
products in those or other markets today.  The Commerce 
Clause is not a general license to regulate an individual
from cradle to grave, simply because he will predictably 
engage in particular transactions.  Any police power to
regulate individuals as such, as opposed to their activities, 
remains vested in the States. 

background image 27 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

The Government argues that the individual mandate

can be sustained as a sort of exception to this rule, because 
health insurance is a unique product.  According to the
Government, upholding the individual mandate would 
not justify mandatory purchases of items such as cars or 
broccoli because, as the Government puts it, “[h]ealth in-
surance is not purchased for its own sake like a car or 
broccoli; it is a means of financing health-care consump-
tion and covering universal risks.”  Reply Brief for United 
States 19.  But cars and broccoli are no more purchased 
for their “own sake” than health insurance.  They are
purchased to cover the need for transportation and food. 

The Government says that health insurance and health

care financing are “inherently integrated.”  Brief for United 
States 41.  But that does not mean the compelled purchase
of the first is properly regarded as a regulation of the
second.  No matter how “inherently integrated” health 
insurance and health care consumption may be, they are
not the same thing: They involve different transactions,
entered into at different times, with different providers.
And for most of those targeted by the mandate, significant 
health care needs will be years, or even decades, away. 
The proximity and degree of connection between the 
mandate and the subsequent commercial activity is too lack-
ing to justify an exception of the sort urged by the Gov-
ernment.  The individual mandate forces individuals 
into commerce precisely because they elected to refrain 
from commercial activity.  Such a law cannot be sus- 
tained under a clause authorizing Congress to “regulate
Commerce.” 

The Government next contends that Congress has the 

power under the Necessary and Proper Clause to enact the
individual mandate because the mandate is an “integral 
part of a comprehensive scheme of economic regulation”— 

background image 28 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

the guaranteed-issue and community-rating insurance
reforms.  Brief for United States 24.  Under this argu-
ment, it is not necessary to consider the effect that an
individual’s inactivity may have on interstate commerce; it
is enough that Congress regulate commercial activity in a
way that requires regulation of inactivity to be effective. 

The power to “make all Laws which shall be necessary 

and proper for carrying into Execution” the powers enu-
merated in the Constitution, Art. I, §8, cl. 18, vests Con-
gress with authority to enact provisions “incidental to the 
[enumerated] power, and conducive to its beneficial exer-
cise,”  McCulloch, 4 Wheat., at 418.  Although the Clause
gives Congress authority to “legislate on that vast mass
of incidental powers which must be involved in the con-
stitution,” it does not license the exercise of any “great
substantive and independent power[s]” beyond those specifi-
cally enumerated.  Id., at 411, 421.  Instead, the Clause is 
“ ‘merely a declaration, for the removal of all uncertainty,
that the means of carrying into execution those [powers] 
otherwise granted are included in the grant.’ ”  Kinsella v. 
United States ex rel. Singleton, 361 U. S. 234, 247 (1960) 
(quoting VI Writings of James Madison 383 (G. Hunt ed.
1906)).

As our jurisprudence under the Necessary and Proper

Clause has developed, we have been very deferential to 
Congress’s determination that a regulation is “necessary.”
We have thus upheld laws that are “ ‘convenient, or use-
ful’ or ‘conducive’ to the authority’s ‘beneficial exercise.’ ”  
Comstock, 560 U. S., at ___ (slip op., at 5) (quoting McCul-
loch
supra, at 413, 418).  But we have also carried out our 
responsibility to declare unconstitutional those laws that 
undermine the structure of government established by the 
Constitution.  Such laws, which are not “consist[ent] with
the letter and spirit of the constitution,” McCullochsupra, 
at 421, are not “proper  [means] for carrying into Execu-
tion” Congress’s enumerated powers.  Rather, they are, “in 

background image 29 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

the words of The Federalist, ‘merely acts of usurpation’ 
which ‘deserve to be treated as such.’ ”  Printz v. United 
States
, 521 U. S. 898, 924 (1997) (alterations omitted) 
(quoting The Federalist No. 33, at 204 (A. Hamilton)); see 
also New York, 505 U. S., at 177; Comstocksupra, at ___ 
(slip op., at 5) (KENNEDY, J., concurring in judgment) (“It
is of fundamental importance to consider whether essen-
tial attributes of state sovereignty are compromised by the 
assertion of federal power under the Necessary and Proper 
Clause . . .”).

Applying these principles, the individual mandate can-

not be sustained under the Necessary and Proper Clause 
as an essential component of the insurance reforms.  Each 
of our prior cases upholding laws under that Clause in-
volved exercises of authority derivative of, and in service
to, a granted power.  For example, we have upheld provi-
sions permitting continued confinement of those already 
in federal custody
 when they could not be safely released, 
Comstock,  supra, at ___ (slip op., at 1–2); criminaliz-
ing bribes involving organizations receiving federal funds
Sabri v. United States, 541 U. S. 600, 602, 605 (2004); and 
tolling state statutes of limitations while cases are pend-
ing in federal court
,  Jinks  v.  Richland County, 538 
U. S. 456, 459, 462 (2003).  The individual mandate, by con-
trast, vests Congress with the extraordinary ability to 
create the necessary predicate to the exercise of an enu-
merated power.

This is in no way an authority that is “narrow in scope,” 

Comstocksupra, at ___ (slip op., at 20), or “incidental” to 
the exercise of the commerce power, McCullochsupra, at 
418.  Rather, such a conception of the Necessary and 
Proper Clause would work a substantial expansion of 
federal authority.  No longer would Congress be limited to
regulating under the Commerce Clause those who by some 
preexisting activity bring themselves within the sphere of 
federal regulation.  Instead, Congress could reach beyond 

background image 30 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

the natural limit of its authority and draw within its 
regulatory scope those who otherwise would be outside of 
it.  Even if the individual mandate is “necessary” to the 
Act’s insurance reforms, such an expansion of federal
power is not a “proper” means for making those reforms 
effective. 

The Government relies primarily on our decision in 

Gonzales  v.  Raich.  In Raich, we considered “comprehen-
sive legislation to regulate the interstate market” in mari-
juana.  545 U. S., at 22.  Certain individuals sought an
exemption from that regulation on the ground that they
engaged in only intrastate possession and consumption.
We denied any exemption, on the ground that marijuana
is a fungible commodity, so that any marijuana could
be readily diverted into the interstate market.  Congress’s
attempt to regulate the interstate market for marijuana
would therefore have been substantially undercut if it 
could not also regulate intrastate possession and con-
sumption.  Id., at 19.  Accordingly, we recognized that
“Congress was acting well within its authority” under the 
Necessary and Proper Clause even though its “regulation
ensnare[d] some purely intrastate activity.”  Id., at 22; see 
also  Perez, 402 U. S., at 154.  Raich  thus did not involve 
the exercise of any “great substantive and independent
power,” McCullochsupra, at 411, of the sort at issue here. 
Instead, it concerned only the constitutionality of “indi-
vidual  applications  of a concededly valid statutory 
scheme.”  Raichsupra, at 23 (emphasis added). 

Just as the individual mandate cannot be sustained as 

a law regulating the substantial effects of the failure to 
purchase health insurance, neither can it be upheld as
a “necessary and proper” component of the insurance re-
forms.  The commerce power thus does not authorize the 
mandate.  Accord, post,  at 4–16 (joint opinion of SCALIA, 

KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting). 

background image 31 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

That is not the end of the matter.  Because the Com-

merce Clause does not support the individual mandate, it
is necessary to turn to the Government’s second argument: 
that the mandate may be upheld as within Congress’s
enumerated power to “lay and collect Taxes.”  Art. I, §8, 
cl. 1. 

The Government’s tax power argument asks us to view 

the statute differently than we did in considering its com-
merce power theory.  In making its Commerce Clause
argument, the Government defended the mandate as a
regulation requiring individuals to purchase health in-
surance.  The Government does not claim that the taxing
power allows Congress to issue such a command.  Instead, 
the Government asks us to read the mandate not as order-
ing individuals to buy insurance, but rather as imposing a 
tax on those who do not buy that product. 

The text of a statute can sometimes have more than one 

possible meaning.  To take a familiar example, a law that 
reads “no vehicles in the park” might, or might not, ban 
bicycles in the park.  And it is well established that if 
a statute has two possible meanings, one of which violates 
the Constitution, courts should adopt the meaning that
does not do so.  Justice Story said that 180 years ago: “No 
court ought, unless the terms of an act rendered it una-
voidable, to give a construction to it which should involve 
a violation, however unintentional, of the constitution.” 
Parsons v. Bedford, 3 Pet. 433, 448449 (1830).  Justice 
Holmes made the same point a century later: “[T]he rule is
settled that as between two possible interpretations of a 
statute, by one of which it would be unconstitutional and 
by the other valid, our plain duty is to adopt that which
will save the Act.”  Blodgett v. Holden, 275 U. S. 142, 148 
(1927) (concurring opinion).

The most straightforward reading of the mandate is

that it commands individuals to purchase insurance. 

background image 32 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

After all, it states that individuals “shall” maintain health 
insurance.  26 U. S. C. §5000A(a).  Congress thought it
could enact such a command under the Commerce Clause, 
and the Government primarily defended the law on that
basis.  But, for the reasons explained above, the Com-
merce Clause does not give Congress that power.  Under 
our precedent, it is therefore necessary to ask whether the
Government’s alternative reading of the statute—that it
only imposes a tax on those without insurance—is a rea-
sonable one. 

Under the mandate, if an individual does not maintain 

health insurance, the only consequence is that he must 
make an additional payment to the IRS when he pays his 
taxes.  See §5000A(b).  That, according to the Government,
means the mandate can be regarded as establishing a
condition—not owning health insurance—that triggers a
tax—the required payment to the IRS.  Under that theory, 
the mandate is not a legal command to buy insurance.
Rather, it makes going without insurance just another 
thing the Government taxes, like buying gasoline or earn-
ing income.  And if the mandate is in effect just a tax hike 
on certain taxpayers who do not have health insurance, it
may be within Congress’s constitutional power to tax.

The question is not whether that is the most natural

interpretation of the mandate, but only whether it is a 
“fairly possible” one.  Crowell v. Benson, 285 U. S. 22, 62 
(1932).  As we have explained, “every reasonable construc-
tion must be resorted to, in order to save a statute from 
unconstitutionality.”  Hooper v. California, 155 U. S. 648, 
657 (1895).  The Government asks us to interpret the 
mandate as imposing a tax, if it would otherwise violate 
the Constitution.  Granting the Act the full measure of 
deference owed to federal statutes, it can be so read, for 
the reasons set forth below. 

background image 33 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of the Court 

The exaction the Affordable Care Act imposes on those 

without health insurance looks like a tax in many re-
spects.  The “[s]hared responsibility payment,” as the
statute entitles it, is paid into the Treasury by “tax-
payer[s]” when they file their tax returns.  26 U. S. C. 
§5000A(b).  It does not apply to individuals who do not 
pay federal income taxes because their household income 
is less than the filing threshold in the Internal Revenue 
Code.  §5000A(e)(2).  For taxpayers who do owe the pay-
ment, its amount is determined by such familiar factors as
taxable income, number of dependents, and joint filing 
status.  §§5000A(b)(3), ©(2), ©(4).  The requirement to
pay is found in the Internal Revenue Code and enforced by 
the IRS, which—as we previously explained—must assess
and collect it “in the same manner as taxes.”  Supra, at 
13–14.  This process yields the essential feature of any tax:
it produces at least some revenue for the Government. 
United States v. Kahriger, 345 U. S. 22, 28, n. 4 (1953). 
Indeed, the payment is expected to raise about $4 billion
per year by 2017.  Congressional Budget Office, Payments
of Penalties for Being Uninsured Under the Patient Pro-
tection and Affordable Care Act (Apr. 30, 2010), in Selected
CBO Publications Related to Health Care Legislation,
2009–2010, p. 71 (rev. 2010). 

It is of course true that the Act describes the payment as

a “penalty,” not a “tax.”  But while that label is fatal to the 
application of the Anti-Injunction Act, supra, at 12–13, it 
does not determine whether the payment may be viewed
as an exercise of Congress’s taxing power.  It is up to Con-
gress whether to apply the Anti-Injunction Act to any
particular statute, so it makes sense to be guided by Con-
gress’s choice of label on that question.  That choice does 
not, however, control whether an exaction is within Con-
gress’s constitutional power to tax.

Our precedent reflects this: In 1922, we decided two 

background image 34 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of the Court 

challenges to the “Child Labor Tax” on the same day.  In 
the first, we held that a suit to enjoin collection of the so-
called tax was barred by the Anti-Injunction Act.  George
259 U. S., at 20.  Congress knew that suits to obstruct 
taxes had to await payment under the Anti-Injunction
Act; Congress called the child labor tax a tax; Congress 
therefore intended the Anti-Injunction Act to apply.  In 
the second case, however, we held that the same exaction, 
although labeled a tax, was not in fact authorized by Con-
gress’s taxing power.  Drexel Furniture, 259 U. S., at 38. 
That constitutional question was not controlled by Con-
gress’s choice of label.

We have similarly held that exactions not labeled taxes 

nonetheless were authorized by Congress’s power to tax.
In the License Tax Cases, for example, we held that federal 
licenses to sell liquor and lottery tickets—for which the 
licensee had to pay a fee—could be sustained as exercises
of the taxing power.  5 Wall., at 471.  And in New York v. 
United States we upheld as a tax a “surcharge” on out-of-
state nuclear waste shipments, a portion of which was 
paid to the Federal Treasury.  505 U. S., at 171.  We thus 
ask whether the shared responsibility payment falls 
within Congress’s taxing power, “[d]isregarding the designa-
tion of the exaction, and viewing its substance and appli-
cation.”  United States v. Constantine, 296 U. S. 287, 294 
(1935); cf. Quill Corp. v. North Dakota, 504 U. S. 298, 310 
(1992) (“[M]agic words or labels” should not “disable an 
otherwise constitutional levy” (internal quotation marks 
omitted)); Nelson v. SearsRoebuck & Co., 312 U. S. 359, 
363 (1941) (“In passing on the constitutionality of a tax 
law, we are concerned only with its practical operation,
not its definition or the precise form of descriptive words
which may be applied to it” (internal quotation marks
omitted));  United States v. Sotelo, 436 U. S. 268, 275 
(1978) (“That the funds due are referred to as a ‘penalty’ 

background image 35 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of the Court 

. . . does not alter their essential character as taxes”).7 

Our cases confirm this functional approach.  For ex-

ample, in Drexel Furniture, we focused on three practical
characteristics of the so-called tax on employing child
laborers that convinced us the “tax” was actually a pen-
alty.  First, the tax imposed an exceedingly heavy bur-
den—10 percent of a company’s net income—on those who 
employed children, no matter how small their infraction. 
Second, it imposed that exaction only on those who know-
ingly employed underage laborers.  Such scienter require-
ments are typical of punitive statutes, because Congress
often wishes to punish only those who intentionally break 
the law.  Third, this “tax” was enforced in part by the
Department of Labor, an agency responsible for pun-
ishing violations of labor laws, not collecting revenue.  259 
U. S., at 36–37; see also, e.g., Kurth Ranch, 511 U. S., at 
780–782 (considering, inter alia, the amount of the exac-
tion, and the fact that it was imposed for violation of a 
separate criminal law); Constantinesupra, at 295 (same).

The same analysis here suggests that the shared re-

sponsibility payment may for constitutional purposes be 
considered a tax, not a penalty: First, for most Americans 
the amount due will be far less than the price of insur-
ance, and, by statute, it can never be more.8  It may often 

—————— 

Sotelo, in particular, would seem to refute the joint dissent’s conten-

tion that we have “never” treated an exaction as a tax if it was denomi-

nated a penalty.  Post,  at 20.  We are not persuaded by the dissent’s 

attempt to distinguish Sotelo as a statutory construction case from the 
bankruptcy context.  Post,  at  17,  n.  5.    The  dissent  itself  treats  the  

question here as one of statutory interpretation, and indeed also relies

on a statutory interpretation case from the bankruptcy context.  Post, 
at 23 (citing United States v. Reorganized CF&I Fabricators of Utah

Inc., 518 U. S. 213, 224 (1996)). 

8

In 2016, for example, individuals making $35,000 a year are ex-

pected to owe the IRS about $60 for any month in which they do not 

have health insurance.  Someone with an annual income of $100,000 a 
year would likely owe about $200.  The price of a qualifying insurance 

background image 36 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of the Court 

be a reasonable financial decision to make the payment 
rather than purchase insurance, unlike the “prohibitory” 
financial punishment in Drexel Furniture.  259 U. S., at 
37.  Second, the individual mandate contains no scienter 
requirement.  Third, the payment is collected solely by the
IRS through the normal means of taxation—except that
the Service is not allowed to use those means most sugges-
tive of a punitive sanction, such as criminal prosecution. 
See §5000A(g)(2).  The reasons the Court in Drexel Furni-
ture
 held that what was called a “tax” there was a penalty 
support the conclusion that what is called a “penalty” here
may be viewed as a tax.9 

None of this is to say that the payment is not intended 

to affect individual conduct.  Although the payment will
raise considerable revenue, it is plainly designed to ex-
pand health insurance coverage.  But taxes that seek to 
influence conduct are nothing new.  Some of our earliest 
federal taxes sought to deter the purchase of imported 
manufactured goods in order to foster the growth of do-
mestic industry.  See W. Brownlee, Federal Taxation in 
America 22 (2d ed. 2004); cf. 2 J. Story, Commentaries on
the Constitution of the United States §962, p. 434 (1833) 
(“the taxing power is often, very often, applied for other
purposes, than revenue”).  Today, federal and state taxes 
can compose more than half the retail price of cigarettes, 
—————— 
policy is projected to be around $400 per month.  See D. Newman, CRS 

Report for Congress, Individual Mandate and Related Information Re-
quirements Under PPACA 7, and n. 25 (2011). 

9

We do not suggest that any exaction lacking a scienter requirement 

and enforced by the IRS is within the taxing power.  See post, at 23–24 
(joint opinion of SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting).

Congress could not, for example, expand its authority to impose crimi-

nal fines by creating strict liability offenses enforced by the IRS rather 
than the FBI.  But the fact the exaction here is paid like a tax, to the

agency that collects taxes—rather than, for example, exacted by De-

partment of Labor inspectors after ferreting out willful malfeasance—
suggests that this exaction may be viewed as a tax. 

background image 37 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of the Court 

not just to raise more money, but to encourage people to 
quit smoking.  And we have upheld such obviously regula-
tory measures as taxes on selling marijuana and sawed-off 
shotguns.  See United States v. Sanchez, 340 U. S. 42, 44– 
45 (1950); Sonzinsky v. United States, 300 U. S. 506, 513 
(1937).  Indeed, “[e]very tax is in some measure regula-
tory.  To some extent it interposes an economic impediment 
to the activity taxed as compared with others not taxed.” 
Sonzinsky,  supra, at 513.  That §5000A seeks to shape 
decisions about whether to buy health insurance does not 
mean that it cannot be a valid exercise of the taxing 
power.

In distinguishing penalties from taxes, this Court has

explained that “if the concept of penalty means anything,
it means punishment for an unlawful act or omission.” 
United States v. Reorganized CF&I Fabricators of Utah
Inc., 518 U. S. 213, 224 (1996); see also United States v. La 
Franca
, 282 U. S. 568, 572 (1931) (“[A] penalty, as the 
word is here used, is an exaction imposed by statute as
punishment for an unlawful act”).  While the individual 
mandate clearly aims to induce the purchase of health 
insurance, it need not be read to declare that failing to do
so is unlawful.  Neither the Act nor any other law attaches 
negative legal consequences to not buying health insur-
ance, beyond requiring a payment to the IRS.  The Gov-
ernment agrees with that reading, confirming that if
someone chooses to pay rather than obtain health insur-
ance, they have fully complied with the law.  Brief for 
United States 60–61; Tr. of Oral Arg. 49–50 (Mar. 26,
2012).

Indeed, it is estimated that four million people each year 

will choose to pay the IRS rather than buy insurance.  See 
Congressional Budget Office, supra, at 71.  We would 
expect Congress to be troubled by that prospect if such
conduct were unlawful.  That Congress apparently regards 
such extensive failure to comply with the mandate as 

background image 38 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of the Court 

tolerable suggests that Congress did not think it was 
creating four million outlaws.  It suggests instead that the
shared responsibility payment merely imposes a tax citi-
zens may lawfully choose to pay in lieu of buying health
insurance. 

The plaintiffs contend that Congress’s choice of lan-

guage—stating that individuals “shall” obtain insurance
or pay a “penalty”—requires reading §5000A as punishing 
unlawful conduct, even if that interpretation would ren-
der the law unconstitutional.  We have rejected a similar 
argument before.  In New York v. United States we exam-
ined a statute providing that “ ‘[e]ach State shall be re-
sponsible for providing . . . for the disposal of . . . low-level 
radioactive waste.’ ”  505 U. S., at 169 (quoting 42 U. S. C. 
§2021c(a)(1)(A)).  A State that shipped its waste to another 
State was exposed to surcharges by the receiving State,
a portion of which would be paid over to the Federal 
Government.  And a State that did not adhere to the 
statutory scheme faced “[p]enalties for failure to comply,”
including increases in the surcharge.  §2021e(e)(2); New 
York
, 505 U. S., at 152–153.  New York urged us to read
the statute as a federal command that the state legisla-
ture enact legislation to dispose of its waste, which would 
have violated the Constitution.  To avoid that outcome, we 
interpreted the statute to impose only “a series of incen-
tives” for the State to take responsibility for its waste.  We 
then sustained the charge paid to the Federal Government 
as an exercise of the taxing power.  Id.,  at 169–174.  We 
see no insurmountable obstacle to a similar approach 
here.10 
—————— 

10

The joint dissent attempts to distinguish New York v. United States 

on the ground that the seemingly imperative language in that case was

in an “introductory provision” that had “no legal consequences.”  Post, 
at 19.  We did not rely on that reasoning in New York.  See 505 U. S., at 

169–170.  Nor could we have.  While the Court quoted only the broad 
statement that “[e]ach State shall be responsible” for its waste, that 

background image 39 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of the Court 

The joint dissenters argue that we cannot uphold

§5000A as a tax because Congress did not “frame” it as
such.  Post,  at 17.  In effect, they contend that even if 
the Constitution permits Congress to do exactly what we 
interpret this statute to do, the law must be struck down
because Congress used the wrong labels.  An example may 
help illustrate why labels should not control here.  Sup-
pose Congress enacted a statute providing that every 
taxpayer who owns a house without energy efficient win-
dows must pay $50 to the IRS.  The amount due is adjusted 
based on factors such as taxable income and joint filing 
status, and is paid along with the taxpayer’s income tax 
return.  Those whose income is below the filing threshold
need not pay.  The required payment is not called a “tax,”
a “penalty,” or anything else.  No one would doubt that 
this law imposed a tax, and was within Congress’s power 
to tax.  That conclusion should not change simply because 
Congress used the word “penalty” to describe the pay-
ment.  Interpreting such a law to be a tax would hardly 
“[i]mpos[e] a tax through judicial legislation.”  Post, at 25. 
Rather, it would give practical effect to the Legislature’s 
enactment. 

Our precedent demonstrates that Congress had the

power to impose the exaction in §5000A under the taxing 
power, and that §5000A need not be read to do more than
impose a tax.  That is sufficient to sustain it.  The “ques-
tion of the constitutionality of action taken by Congress
does not depend on recitals of the power which it under-
takes to exercise.”  Woods v. Cloyd W. Miller Co., 333 U. S. 
—————— 
language was implemented through operative provisions that also use 

the words on which the dissent relies.  See 42 U. S. C. §2021e(e)(1)

(entitled “Requirements for non-sited compact regions and non-member
States” and directing that those entities “shall comply with the follow-

ing requirements”); §2021e(e)(2) (describing “Penalties for failure to

comply”).  The Court upheld those provisions not as lawful commands,
but as “incentives.”  See 505 U. S., at 152–153, 171–173. 

background image 40 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of the Court 

138, 144 (1948).

Even if the taxing power enables Congress to impose 

a tax on not obtaining health insurance, any tax must 
still comply with other requirements in the Constitution. 
Plaintiffs argue that the shared responsibility payment 
does not do so, citing Article I, §9, clause 4.  That clause 
provides: “No Capitation, or other direct, Tax shall be laid, 
unless in Proportion to the Census or Enumeration herein 
before directed to be taken.”  This requirement means that
any “direct Tax” must be apportioned so that each State 
pays in proportion to its population.  According to the 
plaintiffs, if the individual mandate imposes a tax, it is a
direct tax, and it is unconstitutional because Congress 
made no effort to apportion it among the States.

Even when the Direct Tax Clause was written it was 

unclear what else, other than a capitation (also known as
a “head tax” or a “poll tax”), might be a direct tax.  See 
Springer v. United States, 102 U. S. 586, 596–598 (1881).
Soon after the framing, Congress passed a tax on owner-
ship of carriages, over James Madison’s objection that it 
was an unapportioned direct tax.  Id., at 597.  This Court 
upheld the tax, in part reasoning that apportioning such
a tax would make little sense, because it would have re-
quired taxing carriage owners at dramatically different 
rates depending on how many carriages were in their 
home State.  See Hylton v. United States, 3 Dall. 171, 174 
(1796) (opinion of Chase, J.).  The Court was unanimous, 
and those Justices who wrote opinions either directly 
asserted or strongly suggested that only two forms of 
taxation were direct: capitations and land taxes.  See id.
at 175; id., at 177 (opinion of Paterson, J.); id., at 183 
(opinion of Iredell, J.).

That narrow view of what a direct tax might be per-

sisted for a century.  In 1880, for example, we explained that 
direct taxes, within the meaning of the Constitution, are 
only capitation taxes, as expressed in that instrument, 

background image 41 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of the Court 

and taxes on real estate.”  Springer,  supra, at 602.  In 
1895, we expanded our interpretation to include taxes on
personal property and income from personal property, in
the course of striking down aspects of the federal income 
tax.  Pollock v. Farmers’ Loan & Trust Co., 158 U. S. 601, 
618 (1895).  That result was overturned by the Sixteenth
Amendment, although we continued to consider taxes on
personal property to be direct taxes.  See Eisner v. Macom-
ber
, 252 U. S. 189, 218–219 (1920). 

A tax on going without health insurance does not fall 

within any recognized category of direct tax.  It is not a 
capitation.  Capitations are taxes paid by every person, 
“without regard to property, profession, or any other cir-
cumstance
.”  Hylton,  supra, at 175 (opinion of Chase, J.) 
(emphasis altered).  The whole point of the shared respon-
sibility payment is that it is triggered by specific cir-
cumstances—earning a certain amount of income but not 
obtaining health insurance.  The payment is also plainly 
not a tax on the ownership of land or personal property. 
The shared responsibility payment is thus not a direct tax
that must be apportioned among the several States. 

There may, however, be a more fundamental objection 

to a tax on those who lack health insurance.  Even if only
a tax, the payment under §5000A(b) remains a burden 
that the Federal Government imposes for an omission, not 
an act.  If it is troubling to interpret the Commerce Clause 
as authorizing Congress to regulate those who abstain
from commerce, perhaps it should be similarly troubling to
permit Congress to impose a tax for not doing something. 

Three considerations allay this concern.  First, and most 

importantly, it is abundantly clear the Constitution does 
not guarantee that individuals may avoid taxation through
inactivity.  A capitation, after all, is a tax that every-
one must pay simply for existing, and capitations are 
expressly contemplated by the Constitution.  The Court 
today holds that our Constitution protects us from federal 

background image 42 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of the Court 

regulation under the Commerce Clause so long as we ab-
stain from the regulated activity.  But from its creation, 
the Constitution has made no such promise with respect to 
taxes.  See Letter from Benjamin Franklin to M. Le Roy 
(Nov. 13, 1789) (“Our new Constitution is now established 
. . . but in this world nothing can be said to be certain,
except death and taxes”).

Whether the mandate can be upheld under the Com-

merce Clause is a question about the scope of federal 
authority.  Its answer depends on whether Congress can
exercise what all acknowledge to be the novel course of 
directing individuals to purchase insurance.  Congress’s
use of the Taxing Clause to encourage buying something 
is, by contrast, not new.  Tax incentives already promote,
for example, purchasing homes and professional educa-
tions.  See 26 U. S. C. §§163(h), 25A.  Sustaining the 
mandate as a tax depends only on whether Congress has 
properly exercised its taxing power to encourage purchas-
ing health insurance, not whether it can.  Upholding the
individual mandate under the Taxing Clause thus does 
not recognize any new federal power.  It determines that 
Congress has used an existing one. 

Second, Congress’s ability to use its taxing power to

influence conduct is not without limits.  A few of our cases 
policed these limits aggressively, invalidating punitive
exactions obviously designed to regulate behavior other-
wise regarded at the time as beyond federal authority.
See, e.g.United States v. Butler, 297 U. S. 1 (1936); Drexel 
Furniture
, 259 U. S. 20.  More often and more recently 
we have declined to closely examine the regulatory motive
or effect of revenue-raising measures.  See Kahriger, 345 
U. S., at 27–31 (collecting cases).  We have nonetheless 
maintained that “ ‘there comes a time in the extension of 
the penalizing features of the so-called tax when it loses
its character as such and becomes a mere penalty with the 
characteristics of regulation and punishment.’ ”  Kurth 

background image 43 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of the Court 

Ranch, 511 U. S., at 779 (quoting Drexel Furnituresupra
at 38).

We have already explained that the shared responsibil-

ity payment’s practical characteristics pass muster as a
tax under our narrowest interpretations of the taxing 
power.  Supra, at 35–36.  Because the tax at hand is 
within even those strict limits, we need not here decide the 
precise point at which an exaction becomes so punitive
that the taxing power does not authorize it.  It remains 
true, however, that the “ ‘power to tax is not the power to 
destroy while this Court sits.’ ”  Oklahoma Tax Comm’n v. 
Texas Co., 336 U. S. 342, 364 (1949) (quoting Panhandle 
Oil Co.
 v. Mississippi ex rel. Knox, 277 U. S. 218, 223 
(1928) (Holmes, J., dissenting)). 

Third, although the breadth of Congress’s power to tax

is greater than its power to regulate commerce, the taxing
power does not give Congress the same degree of control
over individual behavior.  Once we recognize that Con-
gress may regulate a particular decision under the Com-
merce Clause, the Federal Government can bring its full 
weight to bear.  Congress may simply command individ-
uals to do as it directs.  An individual who disobeys may 
be subjected to criminal sanctions.  Those sanctions can 
include not only fines and imprisonment, but all the at-
tendant consequences of being branded a criminal: depri-
vation of otherwise protected civil rights, such as the right
to bear arms or vote in elections; loss of employment op-
portunities; social stigma; and severe disabilities in other
controversies, such as custody or immigration disputes. 

By contrast, Congress’s authority under the taxing

power is limited to requiring an individual to pay money 
into the Federal Treasury, no more.  If a tax is properly
paid, the Government has no power to compel or punish
individuals subject to it.  We do not make light of the se-
vere burden that taxation—especially taxation motivated
by a regulatory purpose—can impose.  But imposition 

background image 44 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

of a tax nonetheless leaves an individual with a lawful 
choice to do or not do a certain act, so long as he is willing 
to pay a tax levied on that choice.11 

The Affordable Care Act’s requirement that certain in-

dividuals pay a financial penalty for not obtaining health 
insurance may reasonably be characterized as a tax.  Be-
cause the Constitution permits such a tax, it is not our role
to forbid it, or to pass upon its wisdom or fairness. 

JUSTICE  GINSBURG questions the necessity of rejecting

the Government’s commerce power argument, given that 
§5000A can be upheld under the taxing power.  Post, at 37. 
But the statute reads more naturally as a command to buy 
insurance than as a tax, and I would uphold it as a com-
mand if the Constitution allowed it.  It is only because the 
Commerce Clause does not authorize such a command 
that it is necessary to reach the taxing power question. 
And it is only because we have a duty to construe a stat-
ute to save it, if fairly possible, that §5000A can be inter-
preted as a tax.  Without deciding the Commerce Clause 
question, I would find no basis to adopt such a saving 
construction. 

The Federal Government does not have the power to

order people to buy health insurance.  Section 5000A 
would therefore be unconstitutional if read as a command. 
The Federal Government does have the power to impose a
tax on those without health insurance.  Section 5000A is 
—————— 

11

Of course, individuals do not have a lawful choice not to pay a tax

due, and may sometimes face prosecution for failing to do so (although 
not for declining to make the shared responsibility payment, see 26 

U. S. C. §5000A(g)(2)).  But that does not show that the tax restricts the 

lawful choice whether to undertake or forgo the activity on which the tax
is predicated.  Those subject to the individual mandate may lawfully 

forgo health insurance and pay higher taxes, or buy health insurance 

and pay lower taxes.  The only thing they may not lawfully do is not
buy health insurance and not pay the resulting tax. 

background image 45 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

therefore constitutional, because it can reasonably be read 
as a tax. 

IV 

The States also contend that the Medicaid expansion

exceeds Congress’s authority under the Spending Clause. 
They claim that Congress is coercing the States to adopt 
the changes it wants by threatening to withhold all of a
State’s Medicaid grants, unless the State accepts the new 
expanded funding and complies with the conditions that 
come with it.  This, they argue, violates the basic principle 
that the “Federal Government may not compel the States
to enact or administer a federal regulatory program.”  New 
York
, 505 U. S., at 188. 

There is no doubt that the Act dramatically increases

state obligations under Medicaid.  The current Medicaid 
program requires States to cover only certain discrete
categories of needy individuals—pregnant women, chil-
dren, needy families, the blind, the elderly, and the dis-
abled.  42 U. S. C. §1396a(a)(10).  There is no mandatory 
coverage for most childless adults, and the States typically
do not offer any such coverage.  The States also enjoy 
considerable flexibility with respect to the coverage levels 
for parents of needy families.  §1396a(a)(10)(A)(ii).  On 
average States cover only those unemployed parents who
make less than 37 percent of the federal poverty level, and 
only those employed parents who make less than 63 per-
cent of the poverty line.  Kaiser Comm’n on Medicaid and 
the Uninsured, Performing Under Pressure 11, and fig. 11
(2012).

The Medicaid provisions of the Affordable Care Act, in

contrast, require States to expand their Medicaid pro-
grams by 2014 to cover all individuals under the age of 65
with incomes below 133 percent of the federal poverty line.
§1396a(a)(10)(A)(i)(VIII).  The Act also establishes a new 

background image 46 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

“[e]ssential health benefits” package, which States must 
provide to all new Medicaid recipients—a level sufficient
to satisfy a recipient’s obligations under the individual man-
date.  §§1396a(k)(1), 1396u–7(b)(5), 18022(b).  The Af-
fordable Care Act provides that the Federal Government
will pay 100 percent of the costs of covering these newly 
eligible individuals through 2016.  §1396d(y)(1).  In the 
following years, the federal payment level gradually de-
creases, to a minimum of 90 percent.  Ibid.  In light of
the expansion in coverage mandated by the Act, the Federal 
Government estimates that its Medicaid spending will in-
crease by approximately $100 billion per year, nearly 40 
percent above current levels.  Statement of Douglas W.
Elmendorf, CBO’s Analysis of the Major Health Care 
Legislation Enacted in March 2010, p. 14, Table 2 (Mar.
30, 2011).

The Spending Clause grants Congress the power “to pay 

the Debts and provide for the . . . general Welfare of the
United States.”  U. S. Const., Art. I, §8, cl. 1.  We have 
long recognized that Congress may use this power to grant
federal funds to the States, and may condition such a
grant upon the States’ “taking certain actions that Con-
gress could not require them to take.”  College Savings Bank
527 U. S., at 686.  Such measures “encourage a State
to regulate in a particular way, [and] influenc[e] a State’s 
policy choices.”  New York,  supra, at 166.  The con-
ditions imposed by Congress ensure that the funds are 
used by the States to “provide for the . . . general Welfare”
in the manner Congress intended.

At the same time, our cases have recognized limits on

Congress’s power under the Spending Clause to secure 
state compliance with federal objectives.  “We have re-
peatedly characterized . . . Spending Clause legislation as
‘much in the nature of a contract.’ ”  Barnes v. Gorman
536 U. S. 181, 186 (2002) (quoting Pennhurst State School 
and Hospital
 v. Halderman, 451 U. S. 1, 17 (1981)).  The 

background image 47 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

legitimacy of Congress’s exercise of the spending power
“thus rests on whether the State voluntarily and knowingly 
accepts the terms of the ‘contract.’”  Pennhurst,  supra
at 17.  Respecting this limitation is critical to ensuring
that Spending Clause legislation does not undermine the 
status of the States as independent sovereigns in our fed-
eral system.  That system “rests on what might at first 
seem a counterintuitive insight, that ‘freedom is enhanced 
by the creation of two governments, not one.’ ”  Bond, 564 
U. S., at ___ (slip op., at 8) (quoting Alden  v.  Maine, 527 
U. S. 706, 758 (1999)).  For this reason, “the Constitution 
has never been understood to confer upon Congress the
ability to require the States to govern according to Con-
gress’ instructions.”  New Yorksupra, at 162.  Otherwise 
the two-government system established by the Framers 
would give way to a system that vests power in one central 
government, and individual liberty would suffer. 

That insight has led this Court to strike down fed-

eral legislation that commandeers a State’s legislative or
administrative apparatus for federal purposes.  See, e.g., 
Printz
, 521 U. S., at 933 (striking down federal legisla- 
tion compelling state law enforcement officers to perform 
federally mandated background checks on handgun pur-
chasers); New Yorksupra, at 174–175 (invalidating provi-
sions of an Act that would compel a State to either take
title to nuclear waste or enact particular state waste 
regulations).  It has also led us to scrutinize Spending
Clause legislation to ensure that Congress is not using 
financial inducements to exert a “power akin to undue 
influence.”  Steward Machine Co. v. Davis, 301 U. S. 548, 
590 (1937).  Congress may use its spending power to cre-
ate incentives for States to act in accordance with federal 
policies.  But when “pressure turns into compulsion,” ibid.
the legislation runs contrary to our system of federalism. 
“[T]he Constitution simply does not give Congress the 
authority to require the States to regulate.”  New York

background image 48 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

505 U. S., at 178.  That is true whether Congress directly 
commands a State to regulate or indirectly coerces a State 
to adopt a federal regulatory system as its own. 

Permitting the Federal Government to force the States

to implement a federal program would threaten the politi-
cal accountability key to our federal system.  “[W]here the
Federal Government directs the States to regulate, it may
be state officials who will bear the brunt of public disap-
proval, while the federal officials who devised the regu-
latory program may remain insulated from the electoral 
ramifications of their decision.”  Id., at 169.  Spending
Clause programs do not pose this danger when a State has
a legitimate choice whether to accept the federal condi-
tions in exchange for federal funds.  In such a situation, 
state officials can fairly be held politically accountable for 
choosing to accept or refuse the federal offer.  But when 
the State has no choice, the Federal Government can 
achieve its objectives without accountability, just as in 
New York and Printz.  Indeed, this danger is heightened
when Congress acts under the Spending Clause, because 
Congress can use that power to implement federal policy it 
could not impose directly under its enumerated powers. 

We addressed such concerns in Steward Machine.  That 

case involved a federal tax on employers that was abated 
if the businesses paid into a state unemployment plan that 
met certain federally specified conditions.  An employer
sued, alleging that the tax was impermissibly “driv[ing]
the state legislatures under the whip of economic pressure 
into the enactment of unemployment compensation laws 
at the bidding of the central government.”  301 U. S., at 
587.  We acknowledged the danger that the Federal Gov-
ernment might employ its taxing power to exert a “power
akin to undue influence” upon the States.  Id., at 590.  But 
we observed that Congress adopted the challenged tax and
abatement program to channel money to the States that
would otherwise have gone into the Federal Treasury for 

background image 49 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

use in providing national unemployment services.  Con-
gress was willing to direct businesses to instead pay the 
money into state programs only on the condition that the 
money be used for the same purposes.  Predicating tax 
abatement on a State’s adoption of a particular type of un-
employment legislation was therefore a means to “safe-
guard [the Federal Government’s] own treasury.”  Id.,  at 
591.  We held that “[i]n such circumstances, if in no oth-
ers, inducement or persuasion does not go beyond the
bounds of power.”  Ibid

In rejecting the argument that the federal law was a

“weapon[ ] of coercion, destroying or impairing the auton-
omy of the states,” the Court noted that there was no
reason to suppose that the State in that case acted other
than through “her unfettered will.”  Id., at 586, 590. 
Indeed, the State itself did “not offer a suggestion that in
passing the unemployment law she was affected by du-
ress.”  Id., at 589. 

As our decision in Steward Machine confirms, Congress

may attach appropriate conditions to federal taxing and
spending programs to preserve its control over the use of
federal funds.  In the typical case we look to the States to
defend their prerogatives by adopting “the simple expedi-
ent of not yielding” to federal blandishments when they
do not want to embrace the federal policies as their own. 
Massachusetts v. Mellon, 262 U. S. 447, 482 (1923).  The 
States are separate and independent sovereigns.  Some-
times they have to act like it. 

The States, however, argue that the Medicaid expansion

is far from the typical case.  They object that Congress has 
“crossed the line distinguishing encouragement from 
coercion,” New Yorksupra, at 175, in the way it has struc-
tured the funding: Instead of simply refusing to grant the 
new funds to States that will not accept the new condi-
tions, Congress has also threatened to withhold those 
States’ existing Medicaid funds.  The States claim that 

background image 50 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

this threat serves no purpose other than to force unwilling 
States to sign up for the dramatic expansion in health care
coverage effected by the Act.

Given the nature of the threat and the programs at

issue here, we must agree.  We have upheld Congress’s
authority to condition the receipt of funds on the States’ 
complying with restrictions on the use of those funds,
because that is the means by which Congress ensures that 
the funds are spent according to its view of the “general
Welfare.”  Conditions that do not here govern the use
of the funds, however, cannot be justified on that ba- 
sis.  When, for example, such conditions take the form of
threats to terminate other significant independent grants,
the conditions are properly viewed as a means of pressur-
ing the States to accept policy changes.

In 

South Dakota v. Dole, we considered a challenge to a 

federal law that threatened to withhold five percent of a 
State’s federal highway funds if the State did not raise its 
drinking age to 21.  The Court found that the condition 
was “directly related to one of the main purposes for which 
highway funds are expended—safe interstate travel.”  483 
U. S., at 208.  At the same time, the condition was not a 
restriction on how the highway funds—set aside for spec-
ific highway improvement and maintenance efforts—were
to be used. 

We accordingly asked whether “the financial induce-

ment offered by Congress” was “so coercive as to pass the 
point at which ‘pressure turns into compulsion.’”  Id., at 
211 (quoting Steward Machinesupra, at 590).  By “finan-
cial inducement” the Court meant the threat of losing five 
percent of highway funds; no new money was offered to
the States to raise their drinking ages.  We found that the 
inducement was not impermissibly coercive, because
Congress was offering only “relatively mild encouragement
to the States.”  Dole, 483 U. S., at 211.  We observed that 
“all South Dakota would lose if she adheres to her chosen 

background image 51 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

course as to a suitable minimum drinking age is 5%” of
her highway funds.  Ibid.  In fact, the federal funds at 
stake constituted less than half of one percent of South
Dakota’s budget at the time.  See Nat. Assn. of State 
Budget Officers, The State Expenditure Report 59 (1987); 
South Dakota v. Dole, 791 F. 2d 628, 630 (CA8 1986).  In 
consequence, “we conclude[d] that [the] encouragement 
to state action [was] a valid use of the spending power.” 
Dole, 483 U. S., at 212.  Whether to accept the drinking 
age change “remain[ed] the prerogative of the States not 
merely in theory but in fact.”  Id., at 211–212. 

In this case, the financial “inducement” Congress has

chosen is much more than “relatively mild encourage-
ment”—it is a gun to the head.  Section 1396c of the Medi-
caid Act provides that if a State’s Medicaid plan does
not comply with the Act’s requirements, the Secretary of
Health and Human Services may declare that “further
payments will not be made to the State.”  42 U. S. C. 
§1396c.  A State that opts out of the Affordable Care Act’s 
expansion in health care coverage thus stands to lose not 
merely “a relatively small percentage” of its existing Medi-
caid funding, but all of it.  Dolesupra, at 211.  Medicaid 
spending accounts for over 20 percent of the average
State’s total budget, with federal funds covering 50 to 83
percent of those costs.  See Nat. Assn. of State Budget
Officers, Fiscal Year 2010 State Expenditure Report, p. 11,
Table 5 (2011); 42 U. S. C. §1396d(b).  The Federal Gov-
ernment estimates that it will pay out approximately $3.3 
trillion between 2010 and 2019 in order to cover the costs 
of  pre-expansion Medicaid.  Brief for United States 10, 
n. 6.  In addition, the States have developed intricate
statutory and administrative regimes over the course of 
many decades to implement their objectives under existing
Medicaid.  It is easy to see how the Dole Court could con-
clude that the threatened loss of less than half of one 
percent of South Dakota’s budget left that State with a 

background image 52 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

“prerogative” to reject Congress’s desired policy, “not 
merely in theory but in fact.”  483 U. S., at 211–212.  The 
threatened loss of over 10 percent of a State’s overall 
budget, in contrast, is economic dragooning that leaves the
States with no real option but to acquiesce in the Medicaid
expansion.12

 JUSTICE  GINSBURG claims that Dole  is distinguishable

because here “Congress has not threatened to withhold
funds earmarked for any other program.”  Post, at 47.  But 
that begs the question: The States contend that the ex-
pansion is in reality a new program and that Congress is
forcing them to accept it by threatening the funds for the 
existing Medicaid program.  We cannot agree that existing
Medicaid and the expansion dictated by the Affordable 
Care Act are all one program simply because “Congress 
styled” them as such.  Post, at 49.  If the expansion is not 
properly viewed as a modification of the existing Medicaid 
program, Congress’s decision to so title it is irrelevant.13 \\ —————— 

12 

JUSTICE  GINSBURG observes that state Medicaid spending will in-

crease by only 0.8 percent after the expansion.  Post, at 43.  That not 
only ignores increased state administrative expenses, but also assumes

that the Federal Government will continue to fund the expansion at the

current statutorily specified levels.  It is not unheard of, however, for 
the Federal Government to increase requirements in such a manner as

to impose unfunded mandates on the States.  More importantly, the 

size of the new financial burden imposed on a State is irrelevant in

analyzing whether the State has been coerced into accepting that 
burden.  “Your money or your life” is a coercive proposition, whether 

you have a single dollar in your pocket or $500. 

13

Nor, of course, can the number of pages the amendment occu-

pies, or the extent to which the change preserves and works within

the existing program, be dispositive.  Cf. post,  at 49–50 (opinion of 
GINSBURG, J.).  Take, for example, the following hypothetical amend-

ment: “All of a State’s citizens are now eligible for Medicaid.”  That 

change would take up a single line and would not alter any “operational 

aspect[ ] of the program” beyond the eligibility requirements.  Post, at 
49.  Yet it could hardly be argued that such an amendment was a 

permissible modification of Medicaid, rather than an attempt to foist an
entirely new health care system upon the States. 

background image 53 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

Here, the Government claims that the Medicaid expan-

sion is properly viewed merely as a modification of the ex-
isting program because the States agreed that Congress
could change the terms of Medicaid when they signed on 
in the first place.  The Government observes that the 
Social Security Act, which includes the original Medicaid
provisions, contains a clause expressly reserving “[t]he 
right to alter, amend, or repeal any provision” of that 
statute.  42 U. S. C. §1304.  So it does.  But “if Congress
intends to impose a condition on the grant of federal mon-
eys, it must do so unambiguously.”  Pennhurst, 451 U. S., 
at 17.  A State confronted with statutory language reserv-
ing the right to “alter” or “amend” the pertinent provisions
of the Social Security Act might reasonably assume that 
Congress was entitled to make adjustments to the Medi-
caid program as it developed.  Congress has in fact done 
so, sometimes conditioning only the new funding, other 
times both old and new.  See, e.g., Social Security Amend-
ments of 1972, 86 Stat. 1381–1382, 1465 (extending Med-
icaid eligibility, but partly conditioning only the new 
funding); Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1990, 
§4601, 104 Stat. 1388–166 (extending eligibility, and 
conditioning old and new funds). 

The Medicaid expansion, however, accomplishes a shift

in kind, not merely degree.  The original program was de-
signed to cover medical services for four particular cat-
egories of the needy: the disabled, the blind, the elderly, 
and needy families with dependent children.  See 42 
U. S. C. §1396a(a)(10).  Previous amendments to Medicaid 
eligibility merely altered and expanded the boundaries of 
these categories.  Under the Affordable Care Act, Medicaid 
is transformed into a program to meet the health care
needs of the entire nonelderly population with income
below 133 percent of the poverty level.  It is no longer a
program to care for the neediest among us, but rather an
element of a comprehensive national plan to provide uni-

background image 54 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

versal health insurance coverage.14 

Indeed, the manner in which the expansion is struc-

tured indicates that while Congress may have styled the 
expansion a mere alteration of existing Medicaid, it recog-
nized it was enlisting the States in a new health care 
program.  Congress created a separate funding provision
to cover the costs of providing services to any person
made newly eligible by the expansion.  While Congress pays 
50 to 83 percent of the costs of covering individuals cur-
rently enrolled in Medicaid, §1396d(b), once the expansion is 
fully implemented Congress will pay 90 percent of the
costs for newly eligible persons, §1396d(y)(1).  The condi-
tions on use of the different funds are also distinct.  Con-
gress mandated that newly eligible persons receive a level 
of coverage that is less comprehensive than the traditional 
Medicaid benefit package.  §1396a(k)(1); see Brief for
United States 9. 

As we have explained, “[t]hough Congress’ power to

legislate under the spending power is broad, it does not 
include surprising participating States with postac-
ceptance or ‘retroactive’ conditions.”  Pennhurstsupra, at 
25.  A State could hardly anticipate that Congress’s reser-
vation of the right to “alter” or “amend” the Medicaid
program included the power to transform it so dramatically.

JUSTICE GINSBURG claims that in fact this expansion is 

—————— 

14 

JUSTICE GINSBURG suggests that the States can have no objection to 

the Medicaid expansion, because “Congress could have repealed Medi-

caid [and,] [t]hereafter, . . . could have enacted Medicaid II, a new 
program combining the pre-2010 coverage with the expanded coverage 

required by the ACA.”  Post, at 51; see also post, at 38.  But it would 

certainly not be that easy.  Practical constraints would plainly inhibit,
if not preclude, the Federal Government from repealing the existing

program and putting every feature of Medicaid on the table for political 

reconsideration.  Such a massive undertaking would hardly be “ritual-
istic.”  Ibid.  The same is true of JUSTICE  GINSBURG’s suggestion that

Congress could establish Medicaid as an exclusively federal program. 

Post, at 44. 

background image 55 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

no different from the previous changes to Medicaid, such 
that “a State would be hard put to complain that it lacked 
fair notice.”  Post,  at 56.  But the prior change she dis-
cusses—presumably the most dramatic alteration she could 
find—does not come close to working the transformation 
the expansion accomplishes.  She highlights an amend-
ment requiring States to cover pregnant women and in-
creasing the number of eligible children.  Ibid.  But this 
modification can hardly be described as a major change in 
a program that—from its inception—provided health care 
for “families with dependent children.”  Previous Medicaid 
amendments simply do not fall into the same category as 
the one at stake here. 

The Court in Steward Machine did not attempt to “fix 

the outermost line” where persuasion gives way to coer-
cion.  301 U. S., at 591.  The Court found it “[e]nough for 
present purposes that wherever the line may be, this 
statute is within it.”  Ibid.  We have no need to fix a line 
either.  It is enough for today that wherever that line may 
be, this statute is surely beyond it.  Congress may not 
simply “conscript state [agencies] into the national bu-
reaucratic army,” FERC v. Mississippi, 456 U. S. 742, 775 
(1982) (O’Connor, J., concurring in judgment in part and 
dissenting in part), and that is what it is attempting to do 
with the Medicaid expansion. 

Nothing in our opinion precludes Congress from offering 

funds under the Affordable Care Act to expand the availa-
bility of health care, and requiring that States accepting 
such funds comply with the conditions on their use.  What 
Congress is not free to do is to penalize States that choose
not to participate in that new program by taking away
their existing Medicaid funding.  Section 1396c gives the
Secretary of Health and Human Services the authority to 

background image 56 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

do just that.  It allows her to withhold all “further [Medi-
caid] payments . . . to the State” if she determines that the 
State is out of compliance with any Medicaid requirement, 
including those contained in the expansion.  42 U. S. C. 
§1396c.  In light of the Court’s holding, the Secretary 
cannot apply §1396c to withdraw existing Medicaid funds
for failure to comply with the requirements set out in the 
expansion.

That fully remedies the constitutional violation we have 

identified.  The chapter of the United States Code that
contains §1396c includes a severability clause confirming
that we need go no further.  That clause specifies that “[i]f
any provision of this chapter, or the application thereof to 
any person or circumstance, is held invalid, the remainder
of the chapter, and the application of such provision to 
other persons or circumstances shall not be affected thereby.”
§1303.  Today’s holding does not affect the continued ap-
plication of §1396c to the existing Medicaid program.  Nor 
does it affect the Secretary’s ability to withdraw funds pro-
vided under the Affordable Care Act if a State that has 
chosen to participate in the expansion fails to comply with
the requirements of that Act.

This is not to say, as the joint dissent suggests, that we

are “rewriting the Medicaid Expansion.”  Post,  at 48. 
Instead, we determine, first, that §1396c is unconstitu-
tional when applied to withdraw existing Medicaid funds
from States that decline to comply with the expansion. 
We then follow Congress’s explicit textual instruction to 
leave unaffected “the remainder of the chapter, and the
application of [the challenged] provision to other persons 
or circumstances.”  §1303.  When we invalidate an applica-
tion of a statute because that application is unconstitu-
tional, we are not “rewriting” the statute; we are merely 
enforcing the Constitution. 

The question remains whether today’s holding affects

other provisions of the Affordable Care Act.  In considering 

background image 57 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

that question, “[w]e seek to determine what Congress
would have intended in light of the Court’s constitutional
holding.”  United States v. Booker, 543 U. S. 220, 246 
(2005) (internal quotation marks omitted).  Our “touch-
stone for any decision about remedy is legislative intent, 
for a court cannot use its remedial powers to circum- 
vent the intent of the legislature.”  Ayotte v. Planned 
Parenthood of Northern New Eng.
, 546 U. S. 320, 330 
(2006) (internal quotation marks omitted).  The question
here is whether Congress would have wanted the rest of 
the Act to stand, had it known that States would have a 
genuine choice whether to participate in the new Medicaid 
expansion.  Unless it is “evident” that the answer is no, we 
must leave the rest of the Act intact.  Champlin Refining 
Co.
 v. Corporation Comm’n of Okla., 286 U. S. 210, 234 
(1932).

We are confident that Congress would have wanted to

preserve the rest of the Act.  It is fair to say that Congress 
assumed that every State would participate in the Medi-
caid expansion, given that States had no real choice but to
do so.  The States contend that Congress enacted the rest
of the Act with such full participation in mind; they point
out that Congress made Medicaid a means for satisfying 
the mandate, 26 U. S. C. §5000A(f)(1)(A)(ii), and enacted 
no other plan for providing coverage to many low-income 
individuals.  According to the States, this means that the 
entire Act must fall. 

We disagree.  The Court today limits the financial pres-

sure the Secretary may apply to induce States to accept
the terms of the Medicaid expansion.  As a practical mat-
ter, that means States may now choose to reject the ex-
pansion; that is the whole point.  But that does not mean 
all or even any will.  Some States may indeed decline to
participate, either because they are unsure they will be
able to afford their share of the new funding obligations,
or because they are unwilling to commit the administra-

background image 58 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

tive resources necessary to support the expansion.  Other 
States, however, may voluntarily sign up, finding the idea
of expanding Medicaid coverage attractive, particularly
given the level of federal funding the Act offers at the 
outset. 

We have no way of knowing how many States will ac-

cept the terms of the expansion, but we do not believe 
Congress would have wanted the whole Act to fall, simply 
because some may choose not to participate.  The other 
reforms Congress enacted, after all, will remain “fully 
operative as a law,” Champlinsupra, at 234, and will still 
function in a way “consistent with Congress’ basic objec-
tives in enacting the statute,” Booker,  supra, at 259. 
Confident that Congress would not have intended any-
thing different, we conclude that the rest of the Act need
not fall in light of our constitutional holding. 

*  *  * 

The Affordable Care Act is constitutional in part and

unconstitutional in part.  The individual mandate cannot 
be upheld as an exercise of Congress’s power under the 
Commerce Clause.  That Clause authorizes Congress to 
regulate interstate commerce, not to order individuals to 
engage in it.  In this case, however, it is reasonable to con-
strue what Congress has done as increasing taxes on those 
who have a certain amount of income, but choose to go 
without health insurance.  Such legislation is within Con-
gress’s power to tax.

As for the Medicaid expansion, that portion of the Af-

fordable Care Act violates the Constitution by threatening

existing Medicaid funding.  Congress has no authority to 

order the States to regulate according to its instructions.

Congress may offer the States grants and require the 

States to comply with accompanying conditions, but the 

States must have a genuine choice whether to accept the 

offer.  The States are given no such choice in this case: 

background image 59 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of ROBERTS, C. J. 

They must either accept a basic change in the nature of 

Medicaid, or risk losing all Medicaid funding.  The remedy 

for that constitutional violation is to preclude the Federal 

Government from imposing such a sanction.  That remedy

does not require striking down other portions of the Af-

fordable Care Act. 

The Framers created a Federal Government of limited 

powers, and assigned to this Court the duty of enforcing

those limits.  The Court does so today.  But the Court does 

not express any opinion on the wisdom of the Affordable 

Care Act.  Under the Constitution, that judgment is re-

served to the people.

The judgment of the Court of Appeals for the Eleventh 

Circuit is affirmed in part and reversed in part. 

It is so ordered. 

background image _________________ 

_________________ 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES 

Nos. 11–393, 11–398 and 11–400 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

BUSINESS, ET AL., PETITIONERS 

11–393 

v. 

KATHLEEN SEBELIUS, SECRETARY OF HEALTH 

AND HUMAN SERVICES, ET AL. 

DEPARTMENT OF HEALTH AND HUMAN 

SERVICES, ET AL., PETITIONERS 

11–398 

v. 

FLORIDA ET AL. 

11–400 

FLORIDA, ET AL., PETITIONERS 

v. 

DEPARTMENT OF HEALTH AND 

HUMAN SERVICES ET AL. 

ON WRITS OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF 

APPEALS FOR THE ELEVENTH CIRCUIT 

[June 28, 2012]

 JUSTICE  GINSBURG,  with whom JUSTICE  SOTOMAYOR 

joins, and with whom JUSTICE  BREYER and JUSTICE 
KAGAN join as to Parts I, II, III, and IV, concurring in 
part, concurring in the judgment in part, and dissenting in 
part. 

I agree with THE CHIEF JUSTICE that the Anti-Injunction

Act does not bar the Court’s consideration of this case, 
and that the minimum coverage provision is a proper 
exercise of Congress’ taxing power.  I therefore join Parts 
I, II, and III–C of THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE’s opinion.
Unlike THE CHIEF JUSTICE, however, I would hold, alterna­

background image

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

tively, that the Commerce Clause authorizes Congress to
enact the minimum coverage provision.  I would also hold 
that the Spending Clause permits the Medicaid expansion 
exactly as Congress enacted it. 

The provision of health care is today a concern of na­

tional dimension, just as the provision of old-age and 
survivors’ benefits was in the 1930’s.  In the Social Secu- 
rity Act, Congress installed a federal system to provide
monthly benefits to retired wage earners and, eventually,
to their survivors.  Beyond question, Congress could have
adopted a similar scheme for health care.  Congress chose,
instead, to preserve a central role for private insurers and 
state governments.  According to THE CHIEF JUSTICE, the 
Commerce Clause does not permit that preservation.  This 
rigid reading of the Clause makes scant sense and is
stunningly retrogressive. 

Since 1937, our precedent has recognized Congress’

large authority to set the Nation’s course in the economic
and social welfare realm.  See United States v. Darby, 312 
U. S. 100, 115 (1941) (overruling Hammer v. Dagenhart
247 U. S. 251 (1918), and recognizing that “regulations of 
commerce which do not infringe some constitutional prohibi- 
tion are within the plenary power conferred on Congress 
by the Commerce Clause”); NLRB v. Jones & Laughlin 
Steel Corp
., 301 U. S. 1, 37 (1937) (“[The commerce] 
power is plenary and may be exerted to protect interstate
commerce no matter what the source of the dangers which
threaten it.” (internal quotation marks omitted)).  THE 
CHIEF JUSTICE’s crabbed reading of the Commerce Clause 
harks back to the era in which the Court routinely thwarted 
Congress’ efforts to regulate the national economy in
the interest of those who labor to sustain it.  See, e.g., 
Railroad Retirement Bd. v. Alton R. Co., 295 U. S. 330, 
362, 368 (1935) (invalidating compulsory retirement and 

background image

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

pension plan for employees of carriers subject to the Inter­
state Commerce Act; Court found law related essentially
“to the social welfare of the worker, and therefore remote 
from any regulation of commerce as such”).  It is a reading 
that should not have staying power. 

In enacting the Patient Protection and Affordable Care 

Act (ACA), Congress comprehensively reformed the 
national market for health-care products and services.
By any measure, that market is immense.  Collectively,
Americans spent $2.5 trillion on health care in 2009, 
accounting for 17.6% of our Nation’s economy.  42 U. S. C. 
§18091(2)(B) (2006 ed., Supp. IV).  Within the next decade, 
it is anticipated, spending on health care will nearly dou­
ble.  Ibid. 

The health-care market’s size is not its only distinctive

feature.  Unlike the market for almost any other product 
or service, the market for medical care is one in which all 
individuals inevitably participate.  Virtually every person
residing in the United States, sooner or later, will visit 
a doctor or other health-care professional.  See Dept. of
Health and Human Services, National Center for Health 
Statistics, Summary Health Statistics for U. S. Adults: 
National Health Interview Survey 2009, Ser. 10, No. 249, 
p. 124, Table 37 (Dec. 2010) (Over 99.5% of adults above 
65 have visited a health-care professional.).  Most people
will do so repeatedly.  See id., at 115, Table 34 (In 2009 
alone, 64% of adults made two or more visits to a doctor’s 
office.).

When individuals make those visits, they face another 

reality of the current market for medical care: its high 
cost.  In 2010, on average, an individual in the United 
States incurred over $7,000 in health-care expenses. 
Dept. of Health and Human Services, Centers for Medi­
care and Medicaid Services, Historic National Health 

background image

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

Expenditure Data, National Health Expenditures: Se- 
lected Calendar Years 1960–2010 (Table 1).  Over a life­
time, costs mount to hundreds of thousands of dollars.  See 
Alemayahu & Warner, The Lifetime Distribution of
Health Care Costs, in 39 Health Service Research 627, 635 
(June 2004).  When a person requires nonroutine care, the 
cost will generally exceed what he or she can afford to pay. 
A single hospital stay, for instance, typically costs up­
wards of $10,000.  See Dept. of Health and Human Ser­
vices,  Office  of  Health  Policy,  ASPE  Research  Brief:  The
Value of Health Insurance 5 (May 2011).  Treatments for 
many serious, though not uncommon, conditions similarly
cost a substantial sum.  Brief for Economic Scholars as 
Amici Curiae in No. 11–398, p. 10 (citing a study indicat­
ing that, in 1998, the cost of treating a heart attack for the
first 90 days exceeded $20,000, while the annual cost of 
treating certain cancers was more than $50,000).

Although every U. S. domiciliary will incur significant 

medical expenses during his or her lifetime, the time when
care will be needed is often unpredictable.  An accident, a 
heart attack, or a cancer diagnosis commonly occurs with­
out warning.  Inescapably, we are all at peril of needing 
medical care without a moment’s notice.  See, e.g., Camp­
bell, Down the Insurance Rabbit Hole, N. Y. Times, Apr. 5,
2012, p. A23 (telling of an uninsured 32-year-old woman 
who, healthy one day, became a quadriplegic the next due 
to an auto accident).

To manage the risks associated with medical care— 

its high cost, its unpredictability, and its inevitability—
most people in the United States obtain health insurance. 
Many (approximately 170 million in 2009) are insured by 
private insurance companies.  Others, including those
over 65 and certain poor and disabled persons, rely on 
government-funded insurance programs, notably Medicare 
and Medicaid.  Combined, private health insurers and 
State and Federal Governments finance almost 85% of the 

background image

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

medical care administered to U. S. residents.  See Con­
gressional Budget Office, CBO’s 2011 Long-Term Budget
Outlook 37 (June 2011). 

Not all U. S. residents, however, have health insurance. 

In 2009, approximately 50 million people were uninsured,
either by choice or, more likely, because they could not 
afford private insurance and did not qualify for govern­
ment aid.  See Dept. of Commerce, Census Bureau, C.
DeNavas-Walt, B. Proctor, & J. Smith, Income, Poverty,
and Health Insurance Coverage in the United States: 2009, 
p. 23, Table 8 (Sept. 2010).  As a group, uninsured individ­
uals annually consume more than $100 billion in health- 
care services, nearly 5% of the Nation’s total.  Hidden 
Health Tax: Americans Pay a Premium 2 (2009), avail- 
able at http:%%//%%www.familiesusa.org (all Internet mate- 
rial as visited June 25, 2012, and included in Clerk of 
Court’s case file).  Over 60% of those without insurance 
visit a doctor’s office or emergency room in a given year.
See Dept. of Health and Human Services, National Cen- 
ter for Health Statistics, Health—United States—2010, 
p. 282, Table 79 (Feb. 2011). 

The large number of individuals without health insur­

ance, Congress found, heavily burdens the national
health-care market.  See 42 U. S. C. §18091(2).  As just 
noted, the cost of emergency care or treatment for a seri­
ous illness generally exceeds what an individual can afford 
to pay on her own.  Unlike markets for most products, 
however, the inability to pay for care does not mean that 
an uninsured individual will receive no care.  Federal and 
state law, as well as professional obligations and embed­
ded social norms, require hospitals and physicians to
provide care when it is most needed, regardless of the
patient’s ability to pay.  See, e.g., 42 U. S. C. §1395dd; Fla.
Stat. §395.1041(3)(f) (2010); Tex. Health & Safety Code 

background image

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

Ann. §§311.022(a) and (b) (West 2010); American Medical 
Association, Council on Ethical and Judicial Affairs, 
Code of Medical Ethics, Current Opinions: Opinion 8.11—
Neglect of Patient, p. 70 (1998–1999 ed.).

As a consequence, medical-care providers deliver sig- 

nificant amounts of care to the uninsured for which the 
providers receive no payment.  In 2008, for example, hospi- 
tals, physicians, and other health-care professionals
received no compensation for $43 billion worth of the $116
billion in care they administered to those without insur­
ance.  42 U. S. C. §18091(2)(F) (2006 ed., Supp. IV). 

Health-care providers do not absorb these bad debts.

Instead, they raise their prices, passing along the cost 
of uncompensated care to those who do pay reliably: the
government and private insurance companies.  In response, 
private insurers increase their premiums, shifting the 
cost of the elevated bills from providers onto those who 
carry insurance.  The net result: Those with health insur­
ance subsidize the medical care of those without it.  As 
economists would describe what happens, the uninsured 
“free ride” on those who pay for health insurance.

The size of this subsidy is considerable.  Congress found

that the cost-shifting just described “increases family
[insurance] premiums by on average over $1,000 a year.” 
Ibid.  Higher premiums, in turn, render health insurance 
less affordable, forcing more people to go without insur­
ance and leading to further cost-shifting.

And it is hardly just the currently sick or injured among

the uninsured who prompt elevation of the price of health 
care and health insurance.  Insurance companies and 
health-care providers know that some percentage of 
healthy, uninsured people will suffer sickness or injury 
each year and will receive medical care despite their ina­
bility to pay.  In anticipation of this uncompensated care, 
health-care companies raise their prices, and insurers
their premiums.  In other words, because any uninsured 

background image

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

person may need medical care at any moment and because 
health-care companies must account for that risk, every 
uninsured person impacts the market price of medical care
and medical insurance. 

The failure of individuals to acquire insurance has other

deleterious effects on the health-care market.  Because 
those without insurance generally lack access to preventa­
tive care, they do not receive treatment for conditions—
like hypertension and diabetes—that can be successfully 
and affordably treated if diagnosed early on.  See Institute 
of Medicine, National Academies, Insuring America’s 
Health: Principles and Recommendations 43 (2004).  When 
sickness finally drives the uninsured to seek care, once
treatable conditions have escalated into grave health
problems, requiring more costly and extensive interven­
tion.  Id., at 43–44.  The extra time and resources provid­
ers spend serving the uninsured lessens the providers’ 
ability to care for those who do have insurance.  See Kliff, 
High Uninsured Rates Can Kill You—Even if You Have 
Coverage, Washington Post (May 7, 2012) (describing a 
study of California’s health-care market which found
that, when hospitals divert time and resources to provide
uncompensated care, the quality of care the hospitals
deliver to those with insurance drops significantly), availa- 
ble at http:%%//%%www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/ezra-klein/post/
high-uninsured-rates-can-kill-you-even-if-you-have-coverage/2012/
05/07/gIQALNHN8T_print.html. 

States cannot resolve the problem of the uninsured on

their own.  Like Social Security benefits, a universal
health-care system, if adopted by an individual State,
would be “bait to the needy and dependent elsewhere, 
encouraging them to migrate and seek a haven of repose.” 
Helvering v. Davis, 301 U. S. 619, 644 (1937).  See also 
Brief for Commonwealth of Massachusetts as Amicus 

background image

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

Curiae in No. 11–398, p. 15 (noting that, in 2009, Massa­
chusetts’ emergency rooms served thousands of uninsured, 
out-of-state residents).  An influx of unhealthy individuals
into a State with universal health care would result in 
increased spending on medical services.  To cover the 
increased costs, a State would have to raise taxes, and 
private health-insurance companies would have to in­
crease premiums.  Higher taxes and increased insurance
costs would, in turn, encourage businesses and healthy 
individuals to leave the State. 

States that undertake health-care reforms on their own 

thus risk “placing themselves in a position of economic 
disadvantage as compared with neighbors or competitors.” 
Davis, 301 U. S., at 644.  See also Brief for Health Care for 
All, Inc., et al. as Amici Curiae in No. 11–398, p. 4 (“[O]ut­
of-state residents continue to seek and receive millions of 
dollars in uncompensated care in Massachusetts hospitals,
limiting the State’s efforts to improve its health care 
system through the elimination of uncompensated care.”).
Facing that risk, individual States are unlikely to take the 
initiative in addressing the problem of the uninsured, even
though solving that problem is in all States’ best interests.
Congress’ intervention was needed to overcome this collective­
action impasse. 

Aware that a national solution was required, Congress

could have taken over the health-insurance market by
establishing a tax-and-spend federal program like Social 
Security.  Such a program, commonly referred to as a 
single-payer system (where the sole payer is the Federal 
Government), would have left little, if any, room for pri­
vate enterprise or the States.  Instead of going this route, 
Congress enacted the ACA, a solution that retains a ro­
bust role for private insurers and state governments.  To 
make its chosen approach work, however, Congress had to 

background image

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

use some new tools, including a requirement that most 
individuals obtain private health insurance coverage.  See 
26 U. S. C. §5000A (2006 ed., Supp. IV) (the minimum
coverage provision).  As explained below, by employing 
these tools, Congress was able to achieve a practical, alto­
gether reasonable, solution. 

A central aim of the ACA is to reduce the number of 

uninsured U. S. residents.  See 42 U. S. C. §18091(2)(C) 
and (I) (2006 ed., Supp. IV).  The minimum coverage
provision advances this objective by giving potential recip­
ients of health care a financial incentive to acquire insur­
ance.  Per the minimum coverage provision, an individual
must either obtain insurance or pay a toll constructed as a
tax penalty.  See 26 U. S. C. §5000A.

The minimum coverage provision serves a further pur­

pose vital to Congress’ plan to reduce the number of unin­
sured.  Congress knew that encouraging individuals to
purchase insurance would not suffice to solve the problem,
because most of the uninsured are not uninsured by 
choice.1  Of particular concern to Congress were people 
who, though desperately in need of insurance, often cannot
acquire it: persons who suffer from preexisting medical
conditions. 

Before the ACA’s enactment, private insurance compa­

nies took an applicant’s medical history into account when
setting insurance rates or deciding whether to insure an 
individual.  Because individuals with preexisting med- 
—————— 

1

According to one study conducted by the National Center for Health

Statistics, the high cost of insurance is the most common reason why 

individuals lack coverage, followed by loss of one’s job, an employer’s 
unwillingness to offer insurance or an insurers’ unwillingness to cover 

those with preexisting medical conditions, and loss of Medicaid cover­

age.  See Dept. of Health and Human Services, National Center for 

Health Statistics, Summary Health Statistics for the U. S. Population: 
National Health Interview Survey—2009, Ser. 10, No. 248, p. 71, Table 

25 (Dec. 2010).  “[D]id not want or need coverage” received too few re- 

sponses to warrant its own category.  See ibid., n. 2. 

background image 10 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

ical conditions cost insurance companies significantly more
than those without such conditions, insurers routinely re-
fused to insure these individuals, charged them substan­
tially higher premiums, or offered only limited coverage
that did not include the preexisting illness.  See Dept. of 
Health and Human Services, Coverage Denied: How the 
Current Health Insurance System Leaves Millions Behind 
1 (2009) (Over the past three years, 12.6 million non­
elderly adults were denied insurance coverage or charged 
higher premiums due to a preexisting condition.). 

To ensure that individuals with medical histories have 

access to affordable insurance, Congress devised a three­
part solution.  First, Congress imposed a “guaranteed is­
sue” requirement, which bars insurers from denying
coverage to any person on account of that person’s medical
condition or history.  See 42 U. S. C. §§300gg–1, 300gg–3, 
300gg–4(a) (2006 ed., Supp. IV).  Second, Congress required 
insurers to use “community rating” to price their insurance
policies.  See §300gg.  Community rating, in effect, bars
insurance companies from charging higher premiums 
to those with preexisting conditions.

But these two provisions, Congress comprehended, could

not work effectively unless individuals were given a pow­
erful incentive to obtain insurance.  See Hearings before
the House Ways and Means Committee, 111th Cong., 1st 
Sess., 10, 13 (2009) (statement of Uwe Reinhardt) (“[I]m- 
position of community-rated premiums and guaranteed 
issue on a market of competing private health insurers 
will inexorably drive that market into extinction, unless
these two features are coupled with . . . a mandate on 
individual[s] to be insured
.” (emphasis in original)). 

In the 1990’s, several States—including New York, New 

Jersey, Washington, Kentucky, Maine, New Hampshire, 
and Vermont—enacted guaranteed-issue and community­
rating laws without requiring universal acquisition of 
insurance coverage.  The results were disastrous.  “All 

background image 11 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

seven states suffered from skyrocketing insurance pre­
mium costs, reductions in individuals with coverage, and
reductions in insurance products and providers.”  Brief for 
American Association of People with Disabilities et al. as 
Amici Curiae in No. 11–398, p. 9 (hereinafter AAPD Brief).
See also Brief for Governor of Washington Christine 
Gregoire as Amicus Curiae in No. 11–398, pp. 11–14 (de­
scribing the “death spiral” in the insurance market Wash­
ington experienced when the State passed a law requiring 
coverage for preexisting conditions). 

Congress comprehended that guaranteed-issue and 

community-rating laws alone will not work.  When insur­
ance companies are required to insure the sick at afforda­
ble prices, individuals can wait until they become ill to buy 
insurance.  Pretty soon, those in need of immediate medi­
cal care—i.e.,  those who cost insurers the most—become 
the insurance companies’ main customers.  This “adverse 
selection” problem leaves insurers with two choices: They 
can either raise premiums dramatically to cover their 
ever-increasing costs or they can exit the market.  In the 
seven States that tried guaranteed-issue and community­
rating requirements without a minimum coverage provi­
sion, that is precisely what insurance companies did.  See, 
e.g., AAPD Brief 10 (“[In Maine,] [m]any insurance provid­
ers doubled their premiums in just three years or less.”); 
id., at 12 (“Like New York, Vermont saw substantial
increases in premiums after its . . . insurance reform 
measures took effect in 1993.”); Hall, An Evaluation of
New York’s Reform Law, 25 J. Health Pol. Pol’y & L. 71,
91–92 (2000) (Guaranteed-issue and community-rating 
laws resulted in a “dramatic exodus of indemnity insurers
from New York’s individual [insurance] market.”); Brief 
for Barry Friedman et al. as Amici Curiae in No. 11–398, 
p. 17 (“In Kentucky, all but two insurers (one State-run) 
abandoned the State.”).

Massachusetts, Congress was told, cracked the adverse 

background image 12 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

selection problem.  By requiring most residents to obtain
insurance, see Mass. Gen. Laws, ch. 111M, §2 (West 2011), 
the Commonwealth ensured that insurers would not be 
left with only the sick as customers.  As a result, federal 
lawmakers observed, Massachusetts succeeded where 
other States had failed.  See Brief for Commonwealth of 
Massachusetts as Amicus Curiae in No. 11–398, p. 3 (not­
ing that the Commonwealth’s reforms reduced the number
of uninsured residents to less than 2%, the lowest rate in 
the Nation, and cut the amount of uncompensated care 
by a third); 42 U. S. C. §18091(2)(D) (2006 ed., Supp. IV) 
(noting the success of Massachusetts’ reforms).2  In cou­
pling the minimum coverage provision with guaranteed­
issue and community-rating prescriptions, Congress
followed Massachusetts’ lead. 

*  *  * 

In sum, Congress passed the minimum coverage provi­

sion as a key component of the ACA to address an econom­
ic and social problem that has plagued the Nation for 
decades: the large number of U. S. residents who are
unable or unwilling to obtain health insurance.  Whatever 
one thinks of the policy decision Congress made, it was 
Congress’ prerogative to make it.  Reviewed with appro­
priate deference, the minimum coverage provision, allied
to the guaranteed-issue and community-rating prescrip­
tions, should survive measurement under the Commerce 
and Necessary and Proper Clauses. 

II 

The Commerce Clause, it is widely acknowledged, “was 

the Framers’ response to the central problem that gave 
—————— 

2

Despite its success, Massachusetts’ medical-care providers still ad­

minister substantial amounts of uncompensated care, much of that to 

uninsured patients from out-of-state.  See supra, at 7–8. 

background image 13 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

rise to the Constitution itself.”  EEOC v. Wyoming, 460 
U. S. 226, 244, 245, n. 1 (1983) (Stevens, J., concurring) 
(citing sources).  Under the Articles of Confederation, the 
Constitution’s precursor, the regulation of commerce was 
left to the States.  This scheme proved unworkable, be­
cause the individual States, understandably focused on
their own economic interests, often failed to take actions 
critical to the success of the Nation as a whole.  See Vices 
of the Political System of the United States, in James
Madison: Writings 69, 71, ¶5 (J. Rakove ed. 1999) (As a 
result of the “want of concert in matters where common 
interest requires it,” the “national dignity, interest, and reve- 
nue [have] suffered.”).3 

What was needed was a “national Government . . . 

armed with a positive & compleat authority in all cases 
where uniform measures are necessary.”  See Letter from 
James Madison to Edmund Randolph (Apr. 8, 1787), in 9 
Papers of James Madison 368, 370 (R. Rutland ed. 1975). 
See also Letter from George Washington to James Madi­
son (Nov. 30, 1785), in 8 id., at 428, 429 (“We are either a 
United people, or we are not.  If the former, let us, in all 
matters of general concern act as a nation, which ha[s] 
national objects to promote, and a national character 
to support.”).  The Framers’ solution was the Commerce 
Clause, which, as they perceived it, granted Congress the 
authority to enact economic legislation “in all Cases for 
the general Interests of the Union, and also in those Cases 
to which the States are separately incompetent.”  2 Rec­
ords of the Federal Convention of 1787, pp. 131–132, ¶8 
—————— 

3

Alexander Hamilton described the problem this way:  “[Often] it

would be beneficial to all the states to encourage, or suppress[,] a 

particular branch of trade, while it would be detrimental . . . to attempt 

it without the concurrence of the rest.”  The Continentalist No. V, in 3 
Papers of Alexander Hamilton 75, 78 (H. Syrett ed. 1962).  Because the 

concurrence of all States was exceedingly difficult to obtain, Hamilton 

observed, “the experiment would probably be left untried.”  Ibid. 

background image 14 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

(M. Farrand rev. 1966).  See also North American Co. v. 
SEC, 327 U. S. 686, 705 (1946) (“[The commerce power] 
is an affirmative power commensurate with the national
needs.”).

The Framers understood that the “general Interests of 

the Union” would change over time, in ways they could not 
anticipate.  Accordingly, they recognized that the Consti­
tution was of necessity a “great outlin[e],” not a detailed 
blueprint, see McCulloch v. Maryland, 4 Wheat. 316, 407 
(1819), and that its provisions included broad concepts, to 
be “explained by the context or by the facts of the case,”
Letter from James Madison to N. P. Trist (Dec. 1831), in 9
Writings of James Madison 471, 475 (G. Hunt ed. 1910).
“Nothing . . . can be more fallacious,” Alexander Hamilton 
emphasized, “than to infer the extent of any power, proper 
to be lodged in the national government, from . . . its
immediate necessities.  There ought to be a CAPACITY to 
provide for future contingencies[,] as they may happen;
and as these are illimitable in their nature, it is impossible 
safely to limit that capacity.”  The Federalist No. 34, 
pp. 205, 206 (John Harvard Library ed. 2009).  See also 
McCulloch, 4 Wheat., at 415 (The Necessary and Proper 
Clause is lodged “in a constitution[,] intended to endure
for ages to come, and consequently, to be adapted to the 
various crises of human affairs.”). 

Consistent with the Framers’ intent, we have repeatedly

emphasized that Congress’ authority under the Commerce 
Clause is dependent upon “practical” considerations,
including “actual experience.”  Jones & Laughlin Steel 
Corp.
, 301 U. S., at 41–42; see Wickard v. Filburn, 317 
U. S. 111, 122 (1942); United States v. Lopez, 514 U. S. 
549, 573 (1995) (KENNEDY,  J., concurring) (emphasizing 
“the Court’s definitive commitment to the practical con­
ception of the commerce power”).  See also North American 

background image 15 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

Co., 327 U. S., at 705 (“Commerce itself is an intensely 
practical matter.  To deal with it effectively, Congress
must be able to act in terms of economic and financial 
realities.” (citation omitted)).  We afford Congress the
leeway “to undertake to solve national problems directly
and realistically.”  American Power & Light Co. v. SEC
329 U. S. 90, 103 (1946).

Until today, this Court’s pragmatic approach to judging

whether Congress validly exercised its commerce power 
was guided by two familiar principles.  First, Congress has
the power to regulate economic activities “that substan­
tially affect interstate commerce.”  Gonzales v. Raich, 545 
U. S. 1, 17 (2005).  This capacious power extends even to
local activities that, viewed in the aggregate, have a sub­
stantial impact on interstate commerce.  See ibid.  See 
also Wickard, 317 U. S., at 125 (“[E]ven if appellee’s activ- 
ity be local and though it may not be regarded as com­
merce, it may still, whatever its nature, be reached by 
Congress if it exerts a substantial economic effect on 
interstate commerce.” (emphasis added)); Jones & Laugh-
lin Steel Corp.
, 301 U. S., at 37. 

Second, we owe a large measure of respect to Congress 

when it frames and enacts economic and social legislation.
See  Raich, 545 U. S., at 17.  See also Pension Benefit 
Guaranty Corporation
 v. R. A. Gray & Co., 467 U. S. 717, 
729 (1984) (“[S]trong deference [is] accorded legislation in 
the field of national economic policy.”); Hodel v. Indiana
452 U. S. 314, 326 (1981) (“This [C]ourt will certainly not 
substitute its judgment for that of Congress unless the
relation of the subject to interstate commerce and its ef­
fect upon it are clearly non-existent.” (internal quotation
marks omitted)).  When appraising such legislation, we 
ask only (1) whether Congress had a “rational basis” for 
concluding that the regulated activity substantially affects 
interstate commerce, and (2) whether there is a “reasona­
ble connection between the regulatory means selected and 

background image 16 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

the asserted ends.”  Id., at 323–324.  See also Raich, 545 
U. S., at 22; Lopez, 514 U. S., at 557; Hodel v. Virginia 
Surface Mining & Reclamation Assn., Inc.
, 452 U. S. 264, 
277 (1981); Katzenbach v. McClung, 379 U. S. 294, 303 
(1964);  Heart of Atlanta Motel, Inc. v. United States, 379 
U. S. 241, 258 (1964); United States v. Carolene Products 
Co.
, 304 U. S. 144, 152–153 (1938).  In answering these
questions, we presume the statute under review is consti­
tutional and may strike it down only on a “plain showing”
that Congress acted irrationally.  United States v. Morri-
son
, 529 U. S. 598, 607 (2000). 

 Straightforward application of these principles would 
require the Court to hold that the minimum coverage
provision is proper Commerce Clause legislation.  Beyond
dispute, Congress had a rational basis for concluding that
the uninsured, as a class, substantially affect interstate 
commerce.  Those without insurance consume billions of 
dollars of health-care products and services each year.  See 
supra, at 5.  Those goods are produced, sold, and delivered
largely by national and regional companies who routinely 
transact business across state lines.  The uninsured also 
cross state lines to receive care.  Some have medical emer­
gencies while away from home.  Others, when sick, go to a
neighboring State that provides better care for those who
have not prepaid for care.  See supra, at 7–8. 

Not only do those without insurance consume a large

amount of health care each year; critically, as earlier
explained, their inability to pay for a significant portion of 
that consumption drives up market prices, foists costs on
other consumers, and reduces market efficiency and sta­
bility.  See supra, at 5–7.  Given these far-reaching effects
on interstate commerce, the decision to forgo insurance is
hardly inconsequential or equivalent to “doing nothing,” 
ante,  at 20; it is, instead, an economic decision Congress 

background image 17 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

has the authority to address under the Commerce Clause.
See supra, at 14–16.  See also Wickard, 317 U. S., at 128 
(“It is well established by decisions of this Court that
the power to regulate commerce includes the power to regu­
late the prices at which commodities in that commerce are
dealt in and practices affecting such prices.” (emphasis
added)).

The minimum coverage provision, furthermore, bears a

“reasonable connection” to Congress’ goal of protecting the 
health-care market from the disruption caused by individ­
uals who fail to obtain insurance.  By requiring those who
do not carry insurance to pay a toll, the minimum cover­
age provision gives individuals a strong incentive to in­
sure.  This incentive, Congress had good reason to believe, 
would reduce the number of uninsured and, correspond­
ingly, mitigate the adverse impact the uninsured have on
the national health-care market. 

Congress also acted reasonably in requiring uninsured

individuals, whether sick or healthy, either to obtain
insurance or to pay the specified penalty.  As earlier ob­
served, because every person is at risk of needing care at 
any moment, all those who lack insurance, regardless of
their current health status, adversely affect the price of 
health care and health insurance.  See supra, at 6–7. 
Moreover, an insurance-purchase requirement limited to 
those in need of immediate care simply could not work. 
Insurance companies would either charge these individu­
als prohibitively expensive premiums, or, if community­
rating regulations were in place, close up shop.  See supra,
at 9–11.  See also Brief for State of Maryland and 10
Other States et al. as Amici Curiae in No. 11–398, p. 28
(hereinafter Maryland Brief) (“No insurance regime can
survive if people can opt out when the risk insured against
is only a risk, but opt in when the risk materializes.”). 

“[W]here we find that the legislators . . . have a rational 

basis for finding a chosen regulatory scheme necessary to 

background image 18 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

the protection of commerce, our investigation is at an end.”  
Katzenbach, 379 U. S., at 303–304.  Congress’ enactment 
of the minimum coverage provision, which addresses a 
specific interstate problem in a practical, experience­
informed manner, easily meets this criterion. 

Rather than evaluating the constitutionality of the

minimum coverage provision in the manner established by
our precedents, THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE relies on a newly
minted constitutional doctrine.  The commerce power does 
not, THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE announces, permit Congress
to “compe[l] individuals to become active in commerce
by purchasing a product.”  Ante, at 20 (emphasis deleted). 


THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE’s novel constraint on Congress’ 

commerce power gains no force from our precedent and for 
that reason alone warrants disapprobation.  See infra, at 
23–27.  But even assuming, for the moment, that Congress
lacks authority under the Commerce Clause to “compel
individuals not engaged in commerce to purchase an 
unwanted product,” ante, at 18, such a limitation would be 
inapplicable here.  Everyone will, at some point, consume
health-care products and services.  See supra, at 3.  Thus, 
if THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE is correct that an insurance­
purchase requirement can be applied only to those who
“actively” consume health care, the minimum coverage
provision fits the bill.

THE CHIEF JUSTICE  does not dispute that all U. S. resi­

dents participate in the market for health services over 
the course of their lives.  See ante,  at 16 (“Everyone will
eventually need health care at a time and to an extent
they cannot predict.”).  But, THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE insists, 
the uninsured cannot be considered active in the market 

background image 19 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

for health care, because “[t]he proximity and degree of 
connection between the [uninsured today] and [their] 
subsequent commercial activity is too lacking.”  Ante, 
at 27. 

This argument has multiple flaws.  First, more than 

60% of those without insurance visit a hospital or doctor’s
office each year.  See supra, at 5.  Nearly 90% will within
five years.4  An uninsured’s consumption of health care is
thus quite proximate: It is virtually certain to occur in the 
next five years and more likely than not to occur this year. 

Equally evident, Congress has no way of separating 

those uninsured individuals who will need emergency medi- 
cal care today (surely their consumption of medical care
is sufficiently imminent) from those who will not need 
medical services for years to come.  No one knows when an 
emergency will occur, yet emergencies involving the unin­
sured arise daily.  To capture individuals who unexpect- 
edly will obtain medical care in the very near future, then, 
Congress needed to include individuals who will not go to
a doctor anytime soon.  Congress, our decisions instruct,
has authority to cast its net that wide.  See Perez v. United 
States
, 402 U. S. 146, 154 (1971) (“[W]hen it is necessary 
in order to prevent an evil to make the law embrace more 
than the precise thing to be prevented it may do so.” (in­
ternal quotation marks omitted)).5 
—————— 

4

See Dept. of Health and Human Services, National Center for 

Health Statistics, Summary Health Statistics for U. S. Adults: National

Health Interview Survey 2009, Ser. 10, No. 249, p. 124, Table 37 
(Dec. 2010). 

5

Echoing THE CHIEF JUSTICE, the joint dissenters urge that the min­

imum coverage provision impermissibly regulates young people who 
“have no intention of purchasing [medical care]” and are too far “re­

moved from the [health-care] market.”  See post, at 8, 11.  This criticism 

ignores the reality that a healthy young person may be a day away
from needing health care.  See supra, at 4.  A victim of an accident or 

unforeseen illness will consume extensive medical care immediately,
though scarcely expecting to do so. 

background image 20 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

Second, it is Congress’ role, not the Court’s, to delineate 

the boundaries of the market the Legislature seeks to
regulate.  THE CHIEF JUSTICE defines the health-care mar- 
ket as including only those transactions that will occur 
either in the next instant or within some (unspecified) 
proximity to the next instant.  But Congress could reason­
ably have viewed the market from a long-term perspective, 
encompassing all transactions virtually certain to occur
over the next decade, see supra, at 19, not just those oc­
curring here and now.

Third, contrary to THE CHIEF JUSTICE’s contention, our 

precedent does indeed support “[t]he proposition that
Congress may dictate the conduct of an individual today
because of prophesied future activity.”  Ante, at 26.  In 
Wickard, the Court upheld a penalty the Federal Govern­
ment imposed on a farmer who grew more wheat than he
was permitted to grow under the Agricultural Adjustment 
Act of 1938 (AAA).  317 U. S., at 114–115.  He could not 
be penalized, the farmer argued, as he was growing the 
wheat for home consumption, not for sale on the open 
market.  Id., at 119.  The Court rejected this argument. 
Id., at 127–129.  Wheat intended for home consumption,
the Court noted, “overhangs the market, and if induced by
rising prices, tends to flow into the market and check price
increases [intended by the AAA].”  Id., at 128. 

Similar reasoning supported the Court’s judgment in 

Raich, which upheld Congress’ authority to regulate mari­
juana grown for personal use.  545 U. S., at 19.  Home­
grown marijuana substantially affects the interstate mar- 
ket for marijuana, we observed, for “the high demand in
the interstate market will [likely] draw such marijuana
into that market.”  Ibid. 

Our decisions thus acknowledge Congress’ authority,

under the Commerce Clause, to direct the conduct of an 
individual today (the farmer in Wickard, stopped from
growing excess wheat; the plaintiff in Raich, ordered to 

background image 21 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

cease cultivating marijuana) because of a prophesied 
future transaction (the eventual sale of that wheat or
marijuana in the interstate market).  Congress’ actions
are even more rational in this case, where the future 
activity (the consumption of medical care) is certain to
occur, the sole uncertainty being the time the activity will
take place.

Maintaining that the uninsured are not active in the

health-care market, THE CHIEF JUSTICE draws an analogy
to the car market.  An individual “is not ‘active in the car 
market,’ ” THE CHIEF JUSTICE observes, simply because he 
or she may someday buy a car.  Ante, at 25.  The analogy
is inapt.  The inevitable yet unpredictable need for medi­
cal care and the guarantee that emergency care will be
provided when required are conditions nonexistent in
other markets.  That is so of the market for cars, and of 
the market for broccoli as well.  Although an individual 
might buy a car or a crown of broccoli one day, there is no
certainty she will ever do so.  And if she eventually wants 
a car or has a craving for broccoli, she will be obliged to
pay at the counter before receiving the vehicle or nour­
ishment.  She will get no free ride or food, at the expense 
of another consumer forced to pay an inflated price.  See 
Thomas More Law Center v. Obama, 651 F. 3d 529, 565 
(CA6 2011) (Sutton, J., concurring in part) (“Regulating
how citizens pay for what they already receive (health 
care), never quite know when they will need, and in the
case of severe illnesses or emergencies generally will not 
be able to afford, has few (if any) parallels in modern 
life.”).  Upholding the minimum coverage provision on the
ground that all are participants or will be participants in
the health-care market would therefore carry no implica­
tion that Congress may justify under the Commerce
Clause a mandate to buy other products and services. 

Nor is it accurate to say that the minimum coverage

provision “compel[s] individuals . . . to purchase an un­

background image 22 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

wanted product,” ante, at 18, or “suite of products,” post, at 
11, n. 2 (joint opinion of SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and 
ALITO, JJ.).  If unwanted today, medical service secured by
insurance may be desperately needed tomorrow.  Virtually
everyone, I reiterate, consumes health care at some point 
in his or her life.  See supra, at 3.  Health insurance is a 
means of paying for this care, nothing more.  In requiring
individuals to obtain insurance, Congress is therefore not 
mandating the purchase of a discrete, unwanted product.
Rather, Congress is merely defining the terms on which 
individuals pay for an interstate good they consume: 
Persons subject to the mandate must now pay for medical
care in advance (instead of at the point of service) and 
through insurance (instead of out of pocket).  Establishing
payment terms for goods in or affecting interstate com­
merce is quintessential economic regulation well within 
Congress’ domain.  See, e.g., United States v. Wrightwood 
Dairy Co.
, 315 U. S. 110, 118 (1942).  Cf. post, at 13 (joint 
opinion of SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ.) 
(recognizing that “the Federal Government can prescribe
[a commodity’s] quality . . . and even [its price]”).

THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE also calls the minimum coverage

provision an illegitimate effort to make young, healthy 
individuals subsidize insurance premiums paid by the less
hale and hardy.  See ante, at 17, 25–26.  This complaint, 
too, is spurious.  Under the current health-care system, 
healthy persons who lack insurance receive a benefit for 
which they do not pay: They are assured that, if they need 
it, emergency medical care will be available, although they 
cannot afford it.  See supra, at 5–6.  Those who have in­
surance bear the cost of this guarantee.  See ibid.    By
requiring the healthy uninsured to obtain insurance or
pay a penalty structured as a tax, the minimum coverage
provision ends the free ride these individuals currently 
enjoy.

In the fullness of time, moreover, today’s young and 

background image 23 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

healthy will become society’s old and infirm.  Viewed over 
a lifespan, the costs and benefits even out: The young who 
pay more than their fair share currently will pay less than
their fair share when they become senior citizens.  And 
even if, as undoubtedly will be the case, some individuals, 
over their lifespans, will pay more for health insurance 
than they receive in health services, they have little to
complain about, for that is how insurance works.  Every
insured person receives protection against a catastrophic
loss, even though only a subset of the covered class will 
ultimately need that protection. 

In any event, THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE’s limitation of the 

commerce power to the regulation of those actively en­
gaged in commerce finds no home in the text of the Consti­
tution or our decisions.  Article I, §8, of the Constitution 
grants Congress the power “[t]o regulate Commerce . . .
among the several States.”  Nothing in this language im-
plies that Congress’ commerce power is limited to regu- 
lating those actively engaged in commercial transactions. 
Indeed, as the D. C. Circuit observed, “[a]t the time the 
Constitution was [framed], to ‘regulate’ meant,” among
other things, “to require action.”  See Seven-Sky v. Holder
661 F. 3d 1, 16 (2011).

Arguing to the contrary, THE CHIEF JUSTICE notes that 

“the Constitution gives Congress the power to ‘coin 
Money,’ in addition to the power to ‘regulate the Value 
thereof,’ ” and similarly “gives Congress the power to ‘raise 
and support Armies’ and to ‘provide and maintain a Navy,’ in 
addition to the power to ‘make Rules for the Government
and Regulation of the land and naval Forces.’ ”  Ante, at 
18–19 (citing Art. I, §8, cls. 5, 12–14).  In separating the 
power to regulate from the power to bring the subject of 
the regulation into existence, THE CHIEF JUSTICE asserts, 
“[t]he language of the Constitution reflects the natural 

background image 24 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

understanding that the power to regulate assumes there is 
already something to be regulated.”  Ante, at 19. 

This argument is difficult to fathom.  Requiring individ­

uals to obtain insurance unquestionably regulates the inter­
state health-insurance and health-care markets, both of 
them in existence well before the enactment of the ACA. 
See  Wickard, 317 U. S., at 128 (“The stimulation of com­
merce is a use of the regulatory function quite as definitely 
as prohibitions or restrictions thereon.”).  Thus, the “some­
thing to be regulated” was surely there when Congress
created the minimum coverage provision.6 

Nor does our case law toe the activity versus inactiv­

ity line.  In Wickard, for example, we upheld the penalty 
imposed on a farmer who grew too much wheat, even
though the regulation had the effect of compelling farmers
to purchase wheat in the open market.  Id., at 127–129. 
“[F]orcing some farmers into the market to buy what they
could provide for themselves” was, the Court held, a valid
means of regulating commerce.  Id., at 128–129.  In an- 
other context, this Court similarly upheld Congress’ author­
ity under the commerce power to compel an “inactive” land­
holder to submit to an unwanted sale.  See Monongahela 
Nav. Co.
 v. United States, 148 U. S. 312, 335–337 (1893) 
(“[U]pon  the [great] power to regulate commerce[,]” Con­
gress has the authority to mandate the sale of real prop- 
erty to the Government, where the sale is essential to the 
improvement of a navigable waterway (emphasis added)); 
Cherokee Nation v. Southern Kansas R. Co., 135 U. S. 641, 

—————— 

THE CHIEF JUSTICE’s reliance on the quoted passages of the Consti­

tution, see ante, at 18–19, is also dubious on other grounds.  The power 
to “regulate the Value” of the national currency presumably includes 

the power to increase the currency’s worth—i.e., to create value where 

none previously existed.  And if the power to “[r]egulat[e] . . . the land 
and naval Forces” presupposes “there is already [in existence] some­

thing to be regulated,” i.e.,  an Army and a Navy, does Congress lack
authority to create an Air Force? 

background image 25 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

657–659 (1890) (similar reliance on the commerce power 
regarding mandated sale of private property for railroad
construction). 

In concluding that the Commerce Clause does not per­

mit Congress to regulate commercial “inactivity,” and there- 
fore does not allow Congress to adopt the practical solu­
tion it devised for the health-care problem, THE  CHIEF 
JUSTICE views the Clause as a “technical legal conception,” 
precisely what our case law tells us not to do.  Wickard
317 U. S., at 122 (internal quotation marks omitted).  See 
also  supra, at 14–16.  This Court’s former endeavors to 
impose categorical limits on the commerce power have not 
fared well.  In several pre-New Deal cases, the Court
attempted to cabin Congress’ Commerce Clause authority
by distinguishing “commerce” from activity once conceived
to be noncommercial, notably, “production,” “mining,” and 
“manufacturing.”  See, e.g., United States v. E. C. Knight 
Co.
, 156 U. S. 1, 12 (1895) (“Commerce succeeds to manu­
facture, and is not a part of it.”); Carter v. Carter Coal Co.
298 U. S. 238, 304 (1936) (“Mining brings the subject 
matter of commerce into existence.  Commerce disposes of 
it.”).  The Court also sought to distinguish activities hav­
ing a “direct” effect on interstate commerce, and for that
reason, subject to federal regulation, from those having
only an “indirect” effect, and therefore not amenable to
federal control.  See, e.g., A. L. A. Schechter Poultry Corp. 
v.  United States, 295 U. S. 495, 548 (1935) (“[T]he dis- 
tinction between direct and indirect effects of intrastate 
transactions upon interstate commerce must be recognized 
as a fundamental one.”).

These line-drawing exercises were untenable, and the

Court long ago abandoned them.  “[Q]uestions of the power 
of Congress [under the Commerce Clause],” we held in 
Wickard, “are not to be decided by reference to any for- 
mula which would give controlling force to nomenclature such 
as ‘production’ and ‘indirect’ and foreclose consideration of 

background image 26 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

the actual effects of the activity in question upon inter­
state commerce.”  317 U. S., at 120.  See also Morrison
529 U. S., at 641–644 (Souter, J., dissenting) (recounting 
the Court’s “nearly disastrous experiment” with formalis­
tic limits on Congress’ commerce power).  Failing to learn 
from this history, THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE plows ahead with
his formalistic distinction between those who are “active 
in commerce,” ante, at 20, and those who are not. 

It is not hard to show the difficulty courts (and Con­

gress) would encounter in distinguishing statutes that reg­
ulate “activity” from those that regulate “inactivity.”  As 
Judge Easterbrook noted, “it is possible to restate most 
actions as corresponding inactions with the same effect.” 
Archie  v.  Racine, 847 F. 2d 1211, 1213 (CA7 1988) (en 
banc).  Take this case as an example.  An individual who 
opts not to purchase insurance from a private insurer can 
be seen as actively selecting another form of insurance: 
self-insurance.  See Thomas More Law Center, 651 F. 3d, 
at 561 (Sutton, J., concurring in part) (“No one is in­
active when deciding how to pay for health care, as self­
insurance and private insurance are two forms of action
for addressing the same risk.”).  The minimum coverage
provision could therefore be described as regulating activ­
ists in the self-insurance market.7  Wickard  is another 
example.  Did the statute there at issue target activity
(the growing of too much wheat) or inactivity (the farmer’s
failure to purchase wheat in the marketplace)?  If any­
thing, the Court’s analysis suggested the latter.  See 317 
U. S., at 127–129. 

At bottom, THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE’s and the joint dissent­

—————— 

THE CHIEF JUSTICE’s characterization of individuals who choose not 

to purchase private insurance as “doing nothing,” ante,  at 20, is simi­

larly questionable.  A person who self-insures opts against prepayment for
a product the person will in time consume.  When aggregated, exercise 

of that option has a substantial impact on the health-care market.  See 

supra, at 5–7, 16–17.   

background image 27 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

ers’ “view that an individual cannot be subject to Com­
merce Clause regulation absent voluntary, affirmative acts
that enter him or her into, or affect, the interstate mar­
ket expresses a concern for individual liberty that [is] 
more redolent of Due Process Clause arguments.”  Seven-
Sky
, 661 F. 3d, at 19.  See also Troxel v. Granville, 530 
U. S. 57, 65 (2000) (plurality opinion) (“The [Due Process]
Clause also includes a substantive component that pro­
vides heightened protection against government interfer­
ence with certain fundamental rights and liberty inter­
ests.” (internal quotation marks omitted)).  Plaintiffs have 
abandoned any argument pinned to substantive due pro­
cess, however, see 648 F. 3d 1235, 1291, n. 93 (CA11 
2011), and now concede that the provisions here at issue 
do not offend the Due Process Clause.8 

 Underlying THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE’s view that the Com­
merce Clause must be confined to the regulation of active
participants in a commercial market is a fear that the
commerce power would otherwise know no limits.  See, 
e.g., ante, at 23 (Allowing Congress to compel an individ- 
ual not engaged in commerce to purchase a product would 
“permi[t] Congress to reach beyond the natural extent
of its authority, everywhere extending the sphere of its
activity, and drawing all power into its impetuous vortex.”
(internal quotation marks omitted)).  The joint dissenters 
—————— 

8

Some adherents to the joint dissent have questioned the existence of

substantive due process rights.  See McDonald v. Chicago, 561 U. S. 

___, ___ (2010) (THOMAS, J., concurring) (slip op., at 7) (The notion that
the Due Process Clause “could define the substance of th[e] righ[t to

liberty] strains credulity.”); Albright v. Oliver, 510 U. S. 266, 275 (1994) 

(SCALIA, J., concurring) (“I reject the proposition that the Due Process 
Clause guarantees certain (unspecified) liberties[.]”).  Given these 

Justices’ reluctance to interpret the Due Process Clause as guarantee­

ing liberty interests, their willingness to plant such protections in the 
Commerce Clause is striking. 

background image 28 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

express a similar apprehension.  See post,  at 8 (If the
minimum coverage provision is upheld under the com­
merce power then “the Commerce Clause becomes a font of 
unlimited power, . . . the hideous monster whose devour­
ing jaws . . . spare neither sex nor age, nor high nor low,
nor sacred nor profane.” (internal quotation marks omit­
ted)).  This concern is unfounded. 
 First, THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE could certainly uphold the
individual mandate without giving Congress carte blanche 
to enact any and all purchase mandates.  As several times 
noted, the unique attributes of the health-care market
render everyone active in that market and give rise to a 
significant free-riding problem that does not occur in other
markets.  See supra, at 3–7, 16–18, 21. 

Nor would the commerce power be unbridled, absent 

THE CHIEF JUSTICE’s “activity” limitation.  Congress would
remain unable to regulate noneconomic conduct that has 
only an attenuated effect on interstate commerce and is 
traditionally left to state law.  See Lopez, 514 U. S., at 
567;  Morrison, 529 U. S., at 617–619.  In  Lopez, for 
example, the Court held that the Federal Government
lacked power, under the Commerce Clause, to criminalize 
the possession of a gun in a local school zone.  Possessing 
a gun near a school, the Court reasoned, “is in no sense 
an economic activity that might, through repetition else­
where, substantially affect any sort of interstate com­
merce.”  514 U. S., at 567; ibid. (noting that the Court
would have “to pile inference upon inference” to conclude
that gun possession has a substantial effect on commerce).
Relying on similar logic, the Court concluded in Morrison 
that Congress could not regulate gender-motivated vio­
lence, which the Court deemed to have too “attenuated 
[an] effect upon interstate commerce.”  529 U. S., at 615. 

An individual’s decision to self-insure, I have explained,

is an economic act with the requisite connection to inter­
state commerce.  See supra, at 16–17.  Other choices 

background image 29 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

individuals make are unlikely to fit the same or similar 
description.  As an example of the type of regulation he
fears, THE CHIEF JUSTICE cites a Government mandate to 
purchase green vegetables.  Ante, at 22–23.  One could call 
this concern “the broccoli horrible.”  Congress, THE CHIEF 
JUSTICE posits, might adopt such a mandate, reasoning
that an individual’s failure to eat a healthy diet, like the 
failure to purchase health insurance, imposes costs on 
others.  See ibid. 

Consider the chain of inferences the Court would have 

to accept to conclude that a vegetable-purchase mandate
was likely to have a substantial effect on the health-care
costs borne by lithe Americans.  The Court would have to 
believe that individuals forced to buy vegetables would 
then eat them (instead of throwing or giving them away),
would prepare the vegetables in a healthy way (steamed 
or raw, not deep-fried), would cut back on unhealthy foods, 
and would not allow other factors (such as lack of exercise 
or little sleep) to trump the improved diet.9  Such “pil[ing
of] inference upon inference” is just what the Court re­
fused to do in Lopez and Morrison

Other provisions of the Constitution also check congres­

sional overreaching.  A mandate to purchase a particu- 
lar product would be unconstitutional if, for example, the
edict impermissibly abridged the freedom of speech, inter­
fered with the free exercise of religion, or infringed on a 
liberty interest protected by the Due Process Clause. 
—————— 

9

The failure to purchase vegetables in THE CHIEF JUSTICE’s hypothet­

ical, then, is not what leads to higher health-care costs for others; 

rather, it is the failure of individuals to maintain a healthy diet, and

the resulting obesity, that creates the cost-shifting problem.  See ante, 
at  22–23.  Requiring individuals to purchase vegetables is thus 

several steps removed from solving the problem.  The failure to obtain 

health insurance, by contrast, is the immediate cause of the cost-shifting 
Congress sought to address through the ACA.  See supra, at 5–7. 

Requiring individuals to obtain insurance attacks the source of the 
problem directly, in a single step. 

background image 30 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

Supplementing these legal restraints is a formidable 

check on congressional power: the democratic process.  See 
Raich, 545 U. S., at 33; Wickard, 317 U. S., at 120 (repeat­
ing Chief Justice Marshall’s “warning that effective re­
straints on [the commerce power’s] exercise must proceed 
from political rather than judicial processes” (citing Gib-
bons
 v. Ogden, 9 Wheat. 1, 197 (1824)).  As the controversy 
surrounding the passage of the Affordable Care Act at­
tests, purchase mandates are likely to engender political 
resistance.  This prospect is borne out by the behavior of 
state legislators.  Despite their possession of unquestioned 
authority to impose mandates, state governments have
rarely done so.  See Hall, Commerce Clause Challenges to
Health Care Reform, 159 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1825, 1838 (2011).

When contemplated in its extreme, almost any power 

looks dangerous.  The commerce power, hypothetically,
would enable Congress to prohibit the purchase and home
production of all meat, fish, and dairy goods, effectively 
compelling Americans to eat only vegetables.  Cf. Raich
545 U. S., at 9; Wickard, 317 U. S., at 127–129.  Yet no one 
would offer the “hypothetical and unreal possibilit[y],” 
Pullman Co. v. Knott, 235 U. S. 23, 26 (1914), of a vegetar­
ian state as a credible reason to deny Congress the author­
ity ever to ban the possession and sale of goods.  THE 
CHIEF  JUSTICE accepts just such specious logic when he 
cites the broccoli horrible as a reason to deny Congress
the power to pass the individual mandate.  Cf. R. Bork, 
The Tempting of America 169 (1990) (“Judges and lawyers
live on the slippery slope of analogies; they are not supposed
to ski it to the bottom.”).  But see, e.g., post, at 3 (joint opin­
ion of SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ.) (assert­
ing, outlandishly, that if the minimum coverage provision
is sustained, then Congress could make “breathing in and
out the basis for federal prescription”). 

background image 31 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

To bolster his argument that the minimum coverage

provision is not valid Commerce Clause legislation, THE 
CHIEF  JUSTICE emphasizes the provision’s novelty.  See 
ante, at 18 (asserting that “sometimes the most telling 
indication of [a] severe constitutional problem . . . is the 
lack of historical precedent for Congress’s action” (internal
quotation marks omitted)).  While an insurance-purchase 
mandate may be novel, THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE’s argument 
certainly is not.  “[I]n almost every instance of the exer- 
cise of the [commerce] power differences are asserted from 
previous exercises of it and made a ground of attack.” 
Hoke v. United States, 227 U. S. 308, 320 (1913).  See, e.g., 
Brief for Petitioner in Perez v. United States, O. T. 1970, 
No. 600, p. 5 (“unprecedented exercise of power”); Sup- 
plemental Brief for Appellees in Katzenbach v. McClung
O. T. 1964, No. 543, p. 40 (“novel assertion of federal
power”); Brief for Appellee in Wickard v. Filburn, O. T. 
1941, No. 59, p. 6  (“complete departure”).  For decades, 
the Court has declined to override legislation because of 
its novelty, and for good reason.  As our national economy 
grows and changes, we have recognized, Congress must 
adapt to the changing “economic and financial realities.” 
See supra, at 14–15.  Hindering Congress’ ability to do so 
is shortsighted; if history is any guide, today’s constriction
of the Commerce Clause will not endure.  See supra, at 
25–26. 

III 

For the reasons explained above, the minimum coverage

provision is valid Commerce Clause legislation.  See su-
pra,  
Part II.  When viewed as a component of the entire 
ACA, the provision’s constitutionality becomes even plain­
er. 

The Necessary and Proper Clause “empowers Congress 

background image 32 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

to enact laws in effectuation of its [commerce] powe[r] 
that are not within its authority to enact in isolation.” 
Raich, 545 U. S., at 39 (SCALIA, J., concurring in judgment).
Hence, “[a] complex regulatory program . . . can survive a 
Commerce Clause challenge without a showing that every
single facet of the program is independently and directly
related to a valid congressional goal.”  Indiana, 452 U. S., 
at 329, n. 17.  “It is enough that the challenged provisions 
are an integral part of the regulatory program and that
the regulatory scheme when considered as a whole satis­
fies this test.”  Ibid. (collecting cases).  See also Raich
545 U. S., at 24–25 (A challenged statutory provision
fits within Congress’ commerce authority if it is an “essen­
tial par[t] of a larger regulation of economic activity,”
such that, in the absence of the provision, “the regulatory
scheme could be undercut.” (quoting Lopez, 514 U. S., at 
561));  Raich, 545 U. S., at 37 (SCALIA,  J.,  concurring in
judgment) (“Congress may regulate even noneconomic 
local activity if that regulation is a necessary part of
a more general regulation of interstate commerce.  The 
relevant question is simply whether the means chosen are 
‘reasonably adapted’ to the attainment of a legitimate end 
under the commerce power.” (citation omitted)). 

Recall that one of Congress’ goals in enacting the Af­

fordable Care Act was to eliminate the insurance indus­
try’s practice of charging higher prices or denying coverage
to individuals with preexisting medical conditions.  See 
supra, at 9–10.  The commerce power allows Congress to 
ban this practice, a point no one disputes.  See United 
States
 v. South-Eastern Underwriters Assn., 322 U. S. 533, 
545, 552–553 (1944) (Congress may regulate “the methods
by which interstate insurance companies do business.”). 

Congress knew, however, that simply barring insurance

companies from relying on an applicant’s medical history 
would not work in practice.  Without the individual man­
date, Congress learned, guaranteed-issue and community­

background image 33 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

rating requirements would trigger an adverse-selection
death-spiral in the health-insurance market: Insurance
premiums would skyrocket, the number of uninsured 
would increase, and insurance companies would exit the
market.  See supra, at 10–11.  When complemented by an 
insurance mandate, on the other hand, guaranteed issue
and community rating would work as intended, increasing 
access to insurance and reducing uncompensated care.
See supra, at 11–12.  The minimum coverage provision is
thus an “essential par[t] of a larger regulation of economic
activity”; without the provision, “the regulatory scheme
[w]ould be undercut.”  Raich, 545 U. S., at 24–25 (inter- 
nal quotation marks omitted).  Put differently, the mini­
mum coverage provision, together with the guaranteed­
issue and community-rating requirements, is “ ‘reasonably 
adapted’ to the attainment of a legitimate end under
the commerce power”: the elimination of pricing and
sales practices that take an applicant’s medical history 
into account.  See id., at 37 (SCALIA, J., concurring in
judgment). 

Asserting that the Necessary and Proper Clause does

not authorize the minimum coverage provision, THE CHIEF 
JUSTICE focuses on the word “proper.”  A mandate to 
purchase health insurance is not “proper” legislation, THE 
CHIEF  JUSTICE urges, because the command “under­
mine[s] the structure of government established by the 
Constitution.”  Ante, at 28.  If long on rhetoric, THE CHIEF 
JUSTICE’s argument is short on substance. 

THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE cites only two cases in which this

Court concluded that a federal statute impermissibly 
transgressed the Constitution’s boundary between state
and federal authority: Printz v. United States, 521 U. S. 
898 (1997), and New York v. United States, 505 U. S. 
144 (1992).  See ante, at 29.  The statutes at issue in 

background image 34 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

both cases, however, compelled state officials to act on the 
Federal Government’s behalf.  521 U. S., at 925–933 (hold­
ing unconstitutional a statute obligating state law en­
forcement officers to implement a federal gun-control law); 
New York, 505 U. S., at 176–177 (striking down a statute 
requiring state legislators to pass regulations pursuant to 
Congress’ instructions).  “[Federal] laws conscripting state 
officers,” the Court reasoned, “violate state sovereignty
and are thus not in accord with the Constitution.”  Printz, 
521 U. S., at 925, 935; New York, 505 U. S., at 176. 

The minimum coverage provision, in contrast, acts

“directly upon individuals, without employing the States
as intermediaries.”  New York, 505 U. S., at 164.  The 
provision is thus entirely consistent with the Consti­
tution’s design.  See Printz, 521 U. S., at 920 (“[T]he
Framers explicitly chose a Constitution that confers upon 
Congress the power to regulate individuals, not States.” 
(internal quotation marks omitted)).

Lacking case law support for his holding, THE  CHIEF 

JUSTICE nevertheless declares the minimum coverage
provision not “proper” because it is less “narrow in scope” 
than other laws this Court has upheld under the Neces­
sary and Proper Clause.  Ante, at 29 (citing United States 
v. Comstock, 560 U. S. ___ (2010); Sabri v. United States
541 U. S. 600 (2004); Jinks v. Richland County, 538 U. S. 
456 (2003)).  THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE’s reliance on cases in 
which this Court has affirmed Congress’ “broad authority 
to enact federal legislation” under the Necessary and 
Proper Clause, Comstock, 560 U. S., at ___ (slip op., at 5), 
is underwhelming.

Nor does THE CHIEF JUSTICE  pause to explain why the 

power to direct either the purchase of health insurance or, 
alternatively, the payment of a penalty collectible as a tax 
is more far-reaching than other implied powers this Court 
has found meet under the Necessary and Proper Clause.
These powers include the power to enact criminal laws, 

background image 35 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

see, e.g., United States v. Fox, 95 U. S. 670, 672 (1878); the
power to imprison, including civil imprisonment, see, e.g., 
Comstock
, 560 U. S., at ___ (slip op., at 1); and the power 
to create a national bank, see McCulloch, 4 Wheat., at 425. 
See also Jinks, 538 U. S., at 463 (affirming Congress’ 
power to alter the way a state law is applied in state court, 
where the alteration “promotes fair and efficient operation 
of the federal courts”).10 

In failing to explain why the individual mandate threat­

ens our constitutional order, THE CHIEF JUSTICE disserves 
future courts.  How is a judge to decide, when ruling on
the constitutionality of a federal statute, whether Con­
gress employed an “independent power,” ante, at 28, or 
merely a “derivative” one, ante, at 29.  Whether the power
used is “substantive,” ante, at 30, or just “incidental,” ante, 
at 29?  The instruction THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE, in effect, 
provides lower courts: You will know it when you see it.

It is more than exaggeration to suggest that the mini­

mum coverage provision improperly intrudes on “essential 
attributes of state sovereignty.”  Ibid. (internal quotation
marks omitted).  First, the Affordable Care Act does not 
operate “in [an] are[a] such as criminal law enforcement or
education where States historically have been sovereign.” 
Lopez, 514 U. S., at 564.  As evidenced by Medicare, Medi­
caid, the Employee Retirement Income Security Act of
1974 (ERISA), and the Health Insurance Portability and 
Accountability Act of 1996 (HIPAA), the Federal Govern­

—————— 

10

Indeed, Congress regularly and uncontroversially requires individ­

uals who are “doing nothing,” see ante,  at 20, to take action.  Exam­
ples include federal requirements to report for jury duty, 28 U. S. C.

§1866(g) (2006 ed., Supp. IV); to register for selective service, 50

U. S. C. App. §453; to purchase firearms and gear in anticipation of 

service in the Militia, 1 Stat. 271 (Uniform Militia Act of 1792); to turn 
gold currency over to the Federal Government in exchange for paper 

currency, see Nortz v. United States, 294 U. S. 317, 328 (1935); and to
file a tax return, 26 U. S. C. §6012 (2006 ed., Supp. IV). 

background image 36 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

ment plays a lead role in the health-care sector, both as a
direct payer and as a regulator. 

Second, and perhaps most important, the minimum 

coverage provision, along with other provisions of the
ACA, addresses the very sort of interstate problem that
made the commerce power essential in our federal system. 
See supra, at 12–14.  The crisis created by the large num­
ber of U. S. residents who lack health insurance is one of 
national dimension that States are “separately incompe­
tent” to handle.  See supra, at 7–8, 13.  See also Maryland
Brief 15–26 (describing “the impediments to effective state 
policymaking that flow from the interconnectedness of 
each state’s healthcare economy” and emphasizing that
“state-level reforms cannot fully address the problems
associated with uncompensated care”).  Far from tram­
pling on States’ sovereignty, the ACA attempts a federal 
solution for the very reason that the States, acting sepa­
rately, cannot meet the need.  Notably, the ACA serves the 
general welfare of the people of the United States while 
retaining a prominent role for the States.  See id., at 31– 
36 (explaining and illustrating how the ACA affords States
wide latitude in implementing key elements of the Act’s 
reforms).11 

—————— 

11

In a separate argument, the joint dissenters contend that the min­

imum coverage provision is not necessary and proper because it was not 
the “only . . . way” Congress could have made the guaranteed-issue and

community-rating reforms work.  Post,  at 9–10.  Congress could also

have avoided an insurance-market death spiral, the dissenters main­
tain, by imposing a surcharge on those who did not previously purchase 

insurance when those individuals eventually enter the health­

insurance system.  Post, at 10.  Or Congress could “den[y] a full income 
tax credit” to those who do not purchase insurance.  Ibid. 

Neither a surcharge on those who purchase insurance nor the de­

nial of a tax credit to those who do not would solve the problem created

by guaranteed-issue and community-rating requirements.  Neither 

would prompt the purchase of insurance before sickness or injury 
occurred. 

background image 37 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

IV 

In the early 20th century, this Court regularly struck

down economic regulation enacted by the peoples’ repre­
sentatives in both the States and the Federal Government. 
See, e.g., Carter Coal Co., 298 U. S., at 303–304, 309–310; 
Dagenhart, 247 U. S., at 276–277; Lochner v. New York
198 U. S. 45, 64 (1905).  THE CHIEF JUSTICE’s Commerce 
Clause opinion, and even more so the joint dissenters’ 
reasoning, see post,  at 4–16, bear a disquieting resem­
blance to those long-overruled decisions.

Ultimately, the Court upholds the individual mandate

as a proper exercise of Congress’ power to tax and spend
“for the . . . general Welfare of the United States.”  Art. I, 
§8, cl. 1; ante,  at 43–44.  I concur in that determination, 
which makes THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE’s Commerce Clause 
essay all the more puzzling.  Why should THE  CHIEF 
JUSTICE strive so mightily to hem in Congress’ capacity to
meet the new problems arising constantly in our ever­
developing modern economy?  I find no satisfying response
to that question in his opinion.12 \\ —————— 

But even assuming there were “practicable” alternatives to the

minimum coverage provision, “we long ago rejected the view that the 

Necessary and Proper Clause demands that an Act of Congress be

absolutely necessary’ to the exercise of an enumerated power.”  Jinks 
v.  Richland County, 538 U. S. 456, 462 (2003) (quoting McCulloch 

v.  Maryland, 4 Wheat. 316, 414–415 (1819)).  Rather, the statutory 
provision at issue need only be “conducive” and “[reasonably] adapted”

to the goal Congress seeks to achieve.  Jinks, 538 U. S., at 462 (internal 

quotation marks omitted).  The minimum coverage provision meets this 
requirement.  See supra, at 31–33. 

12 

THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE  states that he must evaluate the constitution­

ality of the minimum coverage provision under the Commerce Clause
because the provision “reads more naturally as a command to buy

insurance than as a tax.”  Ante, at 44.  THE CHIEF JUSTICE ultimately

concludes, however, that interpreting the provision as a tax is a “fairly
possible” construction.  Ante, at 32 (internal quotation marks omitted).

That being so, I see no reason to undertake a Commerce Clause analy­
sis that is not outcome determinative. 

background image 38 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

Through Medicaid, Congress has offered the States an

opportunity to furnish health care to the poor with the aid
of federal financing.  To receive federal Medicaid funds, 
States must provide health benefits to specified categories 
of needy persons, including pregnant women, children,
parents, and adults with disabilities.  Guaranteed eligibil­
ity varies by category: for some it is tied to the federal 
poverty level (incomes up to 100% or 133%); for others it 
depends on criteria such as eligibility for designated state 
or federal assistance programs.  The ACA enlarges the
population of needy people States must cover to include
adults under age 65 with incomes up to 133% of the fed- 
eral poverty level.  The spending power conferred by the 
Constitution, the Court has never doubted, permits Con­
gress to define the contours of programs financed with
federal funds.  See, e.g., Pennhurst State School and Hos-
pital
 v. Halderman, 451 U. S. 1, 17 (1981).  And to expand
coverage, Congress could have recalled the existing legis­
lation, and replaced it with a new law making Medicaid as
embracive of the poor as Congress chose.

The question posed by the 2010 Medicaid expansion, 

then, is essentially this: To cover a notably larger popula­
tion, must Congress take the repeal/reenact route, or may
it achieve the same result by amending existing law?  The 
answer should be that Congress may expand by amend­
ment the classes of needy persons entitled to Medicaid
benefits.  A ritualistic requirement that Congress repeal
and reenact spending legislation in order to enlarge the
population served by a federally funded program would 
advance no constitutional principle and would scarcely
serve the interests of federalism.  To the contrary, such a 
requirement would rigidify Congress’ efforts to empower
States by partnering with them in the implementation of 
federal programs.

Medicaid is a prototypical example of federal-state coop­

background image 39 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

eration in serving the Nation’s general welfare.  Rather 
than authorizing a federal agency to administer a uni- 
form national health-care system for the poor, Con-
gress offered States the opportunity to tailor Medicaid
grants to their particular needs, so long as they remain 
within bounds set by federal law.  In shaping Medicaid,
Congress did not endeavor to fix permanently the terms 
participating states must meet; instead, Congress re­
served the “right to alter, amend, or repeal” any provision 
of the Medicaid Act.  42 U. S. C. §1304.  States, for their 
part, agreed to amend their own Medicaid plans consistent
with changes from time to time made in the federal law.
See 42 CFR §430.12©(i) (2011).  And from 1965 to the 
present, States have regularly conformed to Congress’ 
alterations of the Medicaid Act. 

THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE acknowledges that Congress may 

“condition the receipt of [federal] funds on the States’ 
complying with restrictions on the use of those funds,” 
ante, at 50, but nevertheless concludes that the 2010 
expansion is unduly coercive.  His conclusion rests on 
three premises, each of them essential to his theory.  First, 
the Medicaid expansion is, in THE CHIEF JUSTICE’s view, a 
new grant program, not an addition to the Medicaid pro­
gram existing before the ACA’s enactment.  Congress, THE 
CHIEF JUSTICE maintains, has threatened States with the 
loss of funds from an old program in an effort to get them
to adopt a new one.  Second, the expansion was unforesee­
able by the States when they first signed on to Medicaid. 
Third, the threatened loss of funding is so large that the
States have no real choice but to participate in the Medi­
caid expansion.  THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE therefore—for the 
first time ever
—finds an exercise of Congress’ spending 
power unconstitutionally coercive.

Medicaid, as amended by the ACA, however, is not two

spending programs; it is a single program with a constant 
aim—to enable poor persons to receive basic health care 

background image 40 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

when they need it.  Given past expansions, plus express 
statutory warning that Congress may change the re­
quirements participating States must meet, there can be 
no tenable claim that the ACA fails for lack of notice. 
Moreover, States have no entitlement to receive any Medi­
caid funds; they enjoy only the opportunity to accept funds 
on Congress’ terms.  Future Congresses are not bound 
by their predecessors’ dispositions; they have authority to 
spend federal revenue as they see fit.  The Federal Gov­
ernment, therefore, is not, as THE CHIEF JUSTICE charges,
threatening States with the loss of “existing” funds from
one spending program in order to induce them to opt into 
another program.  Congress is simply requiring States to
do what States have long been required to do to receive
Medicaid funding: comply with the conditions Congress
prescribes for participation. 

A majority of the Court, however, buys the argument 

that prospective withholding of funds formerly available
exceeds Congress’ spending power.  Given that holding, I
entirely agree with THE CHIEF JUSTICE as to the appropri­
ate remedy.  It is to bar the withholding found impermis­
sible—not, as the joint dissenters would have it, to scrap 
the expansion altogether, see post, at 46–48.  The dissent­
ers’ view that the ACA must fall in its entirety is a radical
departure from the Court’s normal course.  When a consti­
tutional infirmity mars a statute, the Court ordinarily
removes the infirmity.  It undertakes a salvage operation;
it does not demolish the legislation.  See, e.g., Brockett v. 
Spokane Arcades, Inc., 472 U. S. 491, 504 (1985) (Court’s
normal course is to declare a statute invalid “to the extent 
that it reaches too far, but otherwise [to leave the statute]
intact”).  That course is plainly in order where, as in this 
case, Congress has expressly instructed courts to leave
untouched every provision not found invalid.  See 42 
U. S. C. §1303.  Because THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE finds the 
withholding—not the granting—of federal funds incom­

background image 41 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

patible with the Spending Clause, Congress’ extension of 
Medicaid remains available to any State that affirms its 
willingness to participate. 

Expansion has been characteristic of the Medicaid pro­

gram.  Akin to the ACA in 2010, the Medicaid Act as 
passed in 1965 augmented existing federal grant programs
jointly administered with the States.13    States  were  not  
required to participate in Medicaid.  But if they did, the 
Federal Government paid at least half the costs.  To qual-
ify for these grants, States had to offer a minimum level of 
health coverage to beneficiaries of four federally funded, 
state-administered welfare programs: Aid to Families with 
Dependent Children; Old Age Assistance; Aid to the Blind;
and Aid to the Permanently and Totally Disabled.  See 
Social Security Amendments of 1965, §121(a), 79 Stat. 
343; Schweiker v. Gray Panthers, 453 U. S. 34, 37 (1981). 
At their option, States could enroll additional “medically
needy” individuals; these costs, too, were partially borne by 
the Federal Government at the same, at least 50%, rate. 
Ibid. 

Since 1965, Congress has amended the Medicaid pro­

gram on more than 50 occasions, sometimes quite sizably.
Most relevant here, between 1988 and 1990, Congress 

—————— 

13

Medicaid was “plainly an extension of the existing Kerr-Mills” 

grant program.  Huberfeld, Federalizing Medicaid, 14 U. Pa. J. Const.

L. 431, 444–445 (2011).  Indeed, the “section of the Senate report
dealing with Title XIX”—the title establishing Medicaid—“was entitled,

‘Improvement and Extension of Kerr-Mills Medical Assistance Pro­

gram.’ ”  Stevens & Stevens, Welfare Medicine in America 51 (1974)
(quoting S. Rep. No. 404, 89th Cong., 1st Sess., pt. 1, p. 9 (1965)). 

Setting the pattern for Medicaid, Kerr-Mills reimbursed States for a

portion of the cost of health care provided to welfare recipients if
States met conditions specified in the federal law, e.g.,  participating

States were obliged to offer minimum coverage for hospitalization and 

physician services.  See Huberfeld, supra, at 443–444. 

background image 42 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

required participating States to include among their bene­
ficiaries pregnant women with family incomes up to 133% 
of the federal poverty level, children up to age 6 at the 
same income levels, and children ages 6 to 18 with family 
incomes up to 100% of the poverty level.  See 42 U. S. C. 
§§1396a(a)(10)(A)(i), 1396a(l); Medicare Catastrophic Cov­
erage Act of 1988, §302, 102 Stat. 750; Omnibus Budget
Reconciliation Act of 1989, §6401, 103 Stat. 2258; Om- 
nibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1990, §4601, 104 Stat.
1388–166.  These amendments added millions to the 
Medicaid-eligible population.  Dubay & Kenney, Lessons 
from the Medicaid Expansions for Children and Pregnant 
Women 5 (Apr. 1997). 

Between 1966 and 1990, annual federal Medicaid spend­

ing grew from $631.6 million to $42.6 billion; state 
spending rose to $31 billion over the same period.  See Dept. 
of Health and Human Services, National Health Expendi­
tures by Type of Service and Source of Funds: Calendar
Years 1960 to 2010 (table).14  And between 1990 and 2010, 
federal spending increased to $269.5 billion.  Ibid.    En­
largement of the population and services covered by Medi­
caid, in short, has been the trend. 

Compared to past alterations, the ACA is notable for the 

extent to which the Federal Government will pick up the
tab.  Medicaid’s 2010 expansion is financed largely by 
federal outlays.  In 2014, federal funds will cover 100% 
of the costs for newly eligible beneficiaries; that rate will 
gradually decrease before settling at 90% in 2020.  42 
U. S. C. §1396d(y) (2006 ed., Supp. IV).  By comparison,
federal contributions toward the care of beneficiaries 
eligible pre-ACA range from 50% to 83%, and averaged 
57% between 2005 and 2008.  §1396d(b) (2006 ed., Supp. 

—————— 

14

Available online at http:%%//%%www.cms.gov/Research-Statistics-Data-

and-Systems/Statistics-Trends-and-Reports/NationalHealthExpendData/
NationalHealthAccountsHistorical.html. 

background image 43 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

IV); Dept. of Health and Human Services, Centers for 
Medicare and Medicaid Services, C. Truffer et al., 2010 
Actuarial Report on the Financial Outlook for Medicaid,
p. 20. 

Nor will the expansion exorbitantly increase state Medi­

caid spending.  The Congressional Budget Office (CBO)
projects that States will spend 0.8% more than they would
have, absent the ACA.  See CBO, Spending & Enrollment
Detail for CBO’s March 2009 Baseline.  But see ante, at 
44–45 (“[T]he Act dramatically increases state obligations 
under Medicaid.”); post, at 45 (joint opinion of SCALIA, 
KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ.) (“[A]cceptance of the
[ACA expansion] will impose very substantial costs on 
participating States.”).  Whatever the increase in state 
obligations after the ACA, it will pale in comparison to the 
increase in federal funding.15 

Finally, any fair appraisal of Medicaid would require 

acknowledgment of the considerable autonomy States 
enjoy under the Act.  Far from “conscript[ing] state agen­
cies into the national bureaucratic army,” ante, at 55 
(citing  FERC v. Mississippi, 456 U. S. 742, 775 (1982) 
(O’Connor, J., concurring in judgment in part and dissent­
ing in part) (brackets in original and internal quotation
marks omitted)), Medicaid “is designed to advance cooper­
ative federalism.”  Wisconsin Dept. of Health and Family 
Servs.
 v. Blumer, 534 U. S. 473, 495 (2002) (citing Harris 
v. McRae, 448 U. S. 297, 308 (1980)).  Subject to its basic 

—————— 

15

Even the study on which the plaintiffs rely, see Brief for Petitioners 

10, concludes that “[w]hile most states will experience some increase in
spending, this is quite small relative to the federal matching payments

and low relative to the costs of uncompensated care that [the states]

would bear if the[re] were no health reform.”  See Kaiser Commission 
on Medicaid & the Uninsured, Medicaid Coverage & Spending in

Health Reform 16 (May 2010).  Thus there can be no objection to the 

ACA’s expansion of Medicaid as an “unfunded mandate.”  Quite the 
contrary, the program is impressively well funded. 

background image 44 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

requirements, the Medicaid Act empowers States to “select 
dramatically different levels of funding and coverage,
alter and experiment with different financing and delivery 
modes, and opt to cover (or not to cover) a range of parti- 
cular procedures and therapies.  States have leveraged
this policy discretion to generate a myriad of dramatically 
different Medicaid programs over the past several dec­
ades.”  Ruger, Of Icebergs and Glaciers, 75 Law & Con­
temp. Probs. 215, 233 (2012) (footnote omitted).  The ACA 
does not jettison this approach.  States, as first-line ad­
ministrators, will continue to guide the distribution of 
substantial resources among their needy populations.

The alternative to conditional federal spending, it bears

emphasis, is not state autonomy but state marginaliza­
tion.16  In 1965, Congress elected to nationalize health
coverage for seniors through Medicare.  It could similarly
have established Medicaid as an exclusively federal pro­
gram.  Instead, Congress gave the States the opportunity
to partner in the program’s administration and develop­
ment.  Absent from the nationalized model, of course, is 
the state-level policy discretion and experimentation that 
is Medicaid’s hallmark; undoubtedly the interests of fed­
eralism are better served when States retain a meaning- 
ful role in the implementation of a program of such 
importance.  See Caminker, State Sovereignty and Sub­
ordinacy, 95 Colum. L. Rev. 1001, 1002–1003 (1995) (coopera- 
tive federalism can preserve “a significant role for state
discretion in achieving specified federal goals, where the
alternative is complete federal preemption of any state 
—————— 

16

In 1972, for example, Congress ended the federal cash-assistance

program for the aged, blind, and disabled.  That program previously

had been operated jointly by the Federal and State Governments, as

is the case with Medicaid today.  Congress replaced the cooperative
federal program with the nationalized Supplemental Security In- 

come (SSI) program.  See Schweiker v. Gray Panthers, 453 U. S. 34, 38 
(1981). 

background image 45 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

regulatory role”); Rose-Ackerman, Cooperative Federalism 
and Co-optation, 92 Yale L. J. 1344, 1346 (1983) (“If 
the federal government begins to take full responsibility
for social welfare spending and preempts the states, the
result is likely to be weaker . . . state governments.”).17 

Although Congress “has no obligation to use its Spend­

ing Clause power to disburse funds to the States,” College 
Savings Bank
 v. Florida Prepaid Postsecondary Ed. Ex-
pense Bd.
, 527 U. S. 666, 686 (1999), it has provided Medi­
caid grants notable for their generosity and flexibility.
“[S]uch funds,” we once observed, “are gifts,” id., at 686– 
687, and so they have remained through decades of expan­
sion in their size and scope. 

The Spending Clause authorizes Congress “to pay the

Debts and provide for the . . . general Welfare of the
United States.”  Art. I, §8, cl. 1.  To ensure that federal funds 
granted to the States are spent “to ‘provide for the . . . 
general Welfare’ in the manner Congress intended,” ante
at 46, Congress must of course have authority to impose
limitations on the States’ use of the federal dollars.  This 
Court, time and again, has respected Congress’ prescrip­
tion of spending conditions, and has required States to
abide by them.  See, e.g., Pennhurst, 451 U. S., at 17 
(“[O]ur cases have long recognized that Congress may fix 
the terms on which it shall disburse federal money to the 
States.”).  In particular, we have recognized Congress’ 
prerogative to condition a State’s receipt of Medicaid 

—————— 

17 

THE CHIEF JUSTICE and the joint dissenters perceive in cooperative 

federalism a “threa[t]” to “political accountability.”  Ante, at 48; see 

post, at 34–35.  By that, they mean voter confusion: Citizens upset by
unpopular government action, they posit, may ascribe to state officials

blame more appropriately laid at Congress’ door.  But no such confu­

sion is apparent in this case: Medicaid’s status as a federally funded, 
state-administered program is hardly hidden from view. 

background image 46 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

funding on compliance with the terms Congress set for
participation in the program.  See, e.g., Harris, 448 U. S., 
at 301 (“[O]nce a State elects to participate [in Medicaid], 
it must comply with the requirements of [the Medicaid
Act].”);  Arkansas Dept. of Health and Human Servs. v. 
Ahlborn, 547 U. S. 268, 275 (2006); Frew v. Hawkins, 540 
U. S. 431, 433 (2004); Atkins v. Rivera, 477 U. S. 154, 156– 
157 (1986).

Congress’ authority to condition the use of federal funds

is not confined to spending programs as first launched.
The legislature may, and often does, amend the law, im­
posing new conditions grant recipients henceforth must 
meet in order to continue receiving funds.  See infra, at 54 
(describing Bennett v. Kentucky Dept. of Ed., 470 U. S. 
656, 659–660 (1985) (enforcing restriction added five years
after adoption of educational program)). 

Yes, there are federalism-based limits on the use of 

Congress’ conditional spending power.  In the leading
decision in this area, South Dakota v. Dole, 483 U. S. 203 
(1987), the Court identified four criteria.  The conditions 
placed on federal grants to States must (a) promote the 
“general welfare,” (b) “unambiguously” inform States what 
is demanded of them, © be germane “to the federal inter­
est in particular national projects or programs,” and (d)
not “induce the States to engage in activities that would
themselves be unconstitutional.”  Id., at 207–208, 210 
(internal quotation marks omitted).18 

The Court in Dole mentioned, but did not adopt, a fur­

ther limitation, one hypothetically raised a half-century 
earlier: In “some circumstances,” Congress might be pro­
hibited from offering a “financial inducement . . . so coer­

—————— 

18

Although the plaintiffs, in the proceedings below, did not contest 

the ACA’s satisfaction of these criteria, see 648 F. 3d 1235, 1263 (CA11

2011), THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE appears to rely heavily on the second crite- 

rion.  Compare ante, at 52, 54, with infra, at 52–54. 

background image 47 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

cive as to pass the point at which ‘pressure turns into 
compulsion.’ ”  Id., at 211 (quoting Steward Machine Co. v. 
Davis, 301 U. S. 548, 590 (1937)).  Prior to today’s deci­
sion, however, the Court has never ruled that the terms of 
any grant crossed the indistinct line between temptation
and coercion. 

Dole involved the National Minimum Drinking Age Act, 

23 U. S. C. §158, enacted in 1984.  That Act directed the 
Secretary of Transportation to withhold 5% of the federal 
highway funds otherwise payable to a State if the State 
permitted purchase of alcoholic beverages by persons 
less than 21 years old.  Drinking age was not within the 
authority of Congress to regulate, South Dakota argued,
because the Twenty-First Amendment gave the States
exclusive power to control the manufacture, transporta­
tion, and consumption of alcoholic beverages.  The small 
percentage of highway-construction funds South Dakota
stood to lose by adhering to 19 as the age of eligibility to 
purchase 3.2% beer, however, was not enough to qualify as
coercion, the Court concluded. 

This case does not present the concerns that led the 

Court in Dole even to consider the prospect of coercion.  In 
Dole, the condition—set 21 as the minimum drinking age—
did not tell the States how to use funds Congress pro-
vided for highway construction.  Further, in view of the 
Twenty-First Amendment, it was an open question whether 
Congress could directly impose a national minimum
drinking age. 

The ACA, in contrast, relates solely to the federally 

funded Medicaid program; if States choose not to comply,
Congress has not threatened to withhold funds earmarked 
for any other program.  Nor does the ACA use Medicaid 
funding to induce States to take action Congress itself 
could not undertake.  The Federal Government undoubt­
edly could operate its own health-care program for poor 
persons, just as it operates Medicare for seniors’ health 

background image 48 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

care.  See supra, at 44. 

That is what makes this such a simple case, and the 

Court’s decision so unsettling.  Congress, aiming to assist
the needy, has appropriated federal money to subsidize
state health-insurance programs that meet federal stand­
ards.  The principal standard the ACA sets is that the 
state program cover adults earning no more than 133% of
the federal poverty line.  Enforcing that prescription en­
sures that federal funds will be spent on health care for 
the poor in furtherance of Congress’ present perception of 
the general welfare. 

THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE asserts that the Medicaid expan­

sion creates a “new health care program.”  Ante, at 54. 
Moreover, States could “hardly anticipate” that Congress 
would “transform [the program] so dramatically.”  Ante
at 55.  Therefore, THE CHIEF JUSTICE maintains, Congress’ 
threat to withhold “old” Medicaid funds based on a State’s 
refusal to participate in the “new” program is a “threa[t] to
terminate [an]other . . . independent gran[t].”  Ante, at 50, 
52–53.  And because the threat to withhold a large amount 
of funds from one program “leaves the States with no real
option but to acquiesce [in a newly created program],” THE 
CHIEF  JUSTICE concludes, the Medicaid expansion is un­
constitutionally coercive.  Ante, at 52. 

The starting premise on which THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE’s 

coercion analysis rests is that the ACA did not really
“extend” Medicaid; instead, Congress created an entirely
new program to co-exist with the old.  THE CHIEF JUSTICE 
calls the ACA new, but in truth, it simply reaches more of 
America’s poor than Congress originally covered. 

Medicaid was created to enable States to provide medi­

cal assistance to “needy persons.”  See S. Rep. No. 404, 

background image 49 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

89th Cong., 1st Sess., pt. 1, p. 9 (1965).  See also §121(a), 
79 Stat. 343 (The purpose of Medicaid is to enable States
“to furnish . . . medical assistance on behalf of [certain
persons] whose income and resources are insufficient to
meet the costs of necessary medical services.”).  By bring­
ing health care within the reach of a larger population of
Americans unable to afford it, the Medicaid expansion is 
an extension of that basic aim. 

The Medicaid Act contains hundreds of provisions gov­

erning operation of the program, setting conditions rang­
ing from “Limitation on payments to States for expend- 
itures attributable to taxes,” 42 U. S. C. §1396a(t) (2006 
ed.), to “Medical assistance to aliens not lawfully admitted
for permanent residence,” §1396b(v) (2006 ed. and Supp.
IV).  The Medicaid expansion leaves unchanged the vast 
majority of these provisions; it adds beneficiaries to the 
existing program and specifies the rate at which States
will be reimbursed for services provided to the added bene- 
ficiaries.  See ACA §§2001(a)(1), (3), 124 Stat. 271–272.
The ACA does not describe operational aspects of the
program for these newly eligible persons; for that infor­
mation, one must read the existing Medicaid Act.  See 42 
U. S. C. §§1396–1396v(b) (2006 ed. and Supp. IV). 

Congress styled and clearly viewed the Medicaid expan­

sion as an amendment to the Medicaid Act, not as a “new” 
health-care program.  To the four categories of beneficiar­
ies for whom coverage became mandatory in 1965, and the 
three mandatory classes added in the late 1980’s, see 
supra, at 41–42, the ACA adds an eighth: individuals 
under 65 with incomes not exceeding 133% of the federal 
poverty level.  The expansion is effectuated by §2001 of the
ACA, aptly titled: “Medicaid Coverage for the Lowest
Income Populations.”  124 Stat. 271.  That section amends 
Title 42, Chapter 7, Subchapter XIX: Grants to States for
Medical Assistance Programs.  Commonly known as the
Medicaid Act, Subchapter XIX filled some 278 pages in 

background image 50 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

2006.  Section 2001 of the ACA would add approximately 
three pages.19 

Congress has broad authority to construct or adjust

spending programs to meet its contemporary understand­
ing of “the general Welfare.”  Helvering v. Davis, 301 U. S. 
619, 640–641 (1937).  Courts owe a large measure of re­
spect to Congress’ characterization of the grant programs 
it establishes.  See Steward Machine, 301 U. S., at 594. 
Even if courts were inclined to second-guess Congress’ 
conception of the character of its legislation, how would 
reviewing judges divine whether an Act of Congress, pur­
porting to amend a law, is in reality not an amendment,
but a new creation?  At what point does an extension
become so large that it “transforms” the basic law?

Endeavoring to show that Congress created a new pro­

gram, THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE cites three aspects of the ex­
pansion.  First, he asserts that, in covering those earning
no more than 133% of the federal poverty line, the Medi­
caid expansion, unlike pre-ACA Medicaid, does not “care
for the neediest among us.”  Ante, at 53.  What makes 
that so?  Single adults earning no more than $14,856 per 
year—133% of the current federal poverty level—surely 
rank among the Nation’s poor. 

Second, according to THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE, “Congress

mandated that newly eligible persons receive a level of 
coverage that is less comprehensive than the traditional 
Medicaid benefit package.”  Ibid.  That less comprehensive 
benefit package, however, is not an innovation introduced
by the ACA; since 2006, States have been free to use it for 
many of their Medicaid beneficiaries.20  The level of bene­
—————— 

19

Compare Subchapter XIX, 42 U. S. C. §§1396–1396v(b) (2006 ed. 

and Supp. IV) with §§1396a(a) (10)(A)(i)(VIII) (2006 ed. and Supp. 
IV); 1396a(a) (10)(A)(ii)(XX), 1396a(a)(75), 1396a(k), 1396a(gg) to (hh),

1396d(y), 1396r–1(e), 1396u–7(b)(5) to (6). 

20

The Deficit Reduction Act of 2005 authorized States to provide

“benchmark coverage” or “benchmark equivalent coverage” to certain 

background image 51 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

fits offered therefore does not set apart post-ACA Medicaid
recipients from all those entitled to benefits pre-ACA.
 Third, THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE correctly notes that the 
reimbursement rate for participating States is differ­
ent regarding individuals who became Medicaid-eligible 
through the ACA.  Ibid.  But the rate differs only in its 
generosity to participating States.  Under pre-ACA Medi­
caid, the Federal Government pays up to 83% of the costs 
of coverage for current enrollees, §1396d(b) (2006 ed. and 
Supp. IV); under the ACA, the federal contribution starts 
at 100% and will eventually settle at 90%, §1396d(y). 
Even if one agreed that a change of as little as 7 percent­
age points carries constitutional significance, is it not
passing strange to suggest that the purported incursion on 
state sovereignty might have been averted, or at least 
mitigated, had Congress offered States less money to carry 
out the same obligations? 

Consider also that Congress could have repealed Medi­

caid.  See supra, at 38–39 (citing 42 U. S. C. §1304); Brief 
for Petitioners in No. 11–400, p. 41.  Thereafter, Congress
could have enacted Medicaid II, a new program combin­
ing the pre-2010 coverage with the expanded coverage
required by the ACA.  By what right does a court stop 
Congress from building up without first tearing down? 

THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE finds the Medicaid expansion vul­

nerable because it took participating States by surprise. 
Ante, at 54.  “A State could hardly anticipate that Con­
gres[s]” would endeavor to “transform [the Medicaid pro­
gram] so dramatically,” he states.  Ante, at 54–55.  For the 
notion that States must be able to foresee, when they sign
up, alterations Congress might make later on, THE CHIEF 
—————— 
Medicaid populations.  See §6044, 120 Stat. 88, 42 U. S. C. §1396u–7

(2006 ed. and Supp. IV).  States may offer the same level of coverage to
persons newly eligible under the ACA.  See §1396a(k). 

background image 52 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

JUSTICE cites only one case: Pennhurst State School and 
Hospital
 v. Halderman, 451 U. S. 1. 

In 

Pennhurst, residents of a state-run, federally funded

institution for the mentally disabled complained of abu­
sive treatment and inhumane conditions in alleged viola­
tion of the Developmentally Disabled Assistance and Bill
of Rights Act.  451 U. S., at 5–6.  We held that the State 
was not answerable in damages for violating conditions
it did not “voluntarily and knowingly accep[t].”  Id., at 17, 
27.  Inspecting the statutory language and legislative his­
tory, we found that the Act did not “unambiguously” im­
pose the requirement on which the plaintiffs relied: that
they receive appropriate treatment in the least restrictive
environment.  Id., at 17–18.  Satisfied that Congress had 
not clearly conditioned the States’ receipt of federal funds
on the States’ provision of such treatment, we declined to
read such a requirement into the Act.  Congress’ spending
power, we concluded, “does not include surprising partici­
pating States with postacceptance or ‘retroactive’ condi­
tions.”  Id., at 24–25. 

Pennhurst  thus instructs that “if Congress intends to 

impose a condition on the grant of federal moneys, it must 
do so unambiguously.”  Ante,  at 53 (quoting Pennhurst
451 U. S., at 17).  That requirement is met in this case.
Section 2001 does not take effect until 2014.  The ACA 
makes perfectly clear what will be required of States that 
accept Medicaid funding after that date: They must extend
eligibility to adults with incomes no more than 133% of 
the federal poverty line.  See 42 U. S. C. §1396a(a)(10)(A) 
(i)(VIII) (2006 ed. and Supp. IV). 

THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE appears to find in Pennhurst  

requirement that, when spending legislation is first 
passed, or when States first enlist in the federal program, 
Congress must provide clear notice of conditions it might
later impose.  If I understand his point correctly, it was
incumbent on Congress, in 1965, to warn the States clearly 

background image 53 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

of the size and shape potential changes to Medicaid might 
take.  And absent such notice, sizable changes could not be
made mandatory.  Our decisions do not support such a 
requirement.21\\  In Bennett v. New Jersey, 470 U. S. 632 (1985), the
Secretary of Education sought to recoup Title I funds22 
based on the State’s noncompliance, from 1970 to 1972, 
with a 1978 amendment to Title I.  Relying on Pennhurst
we rejected the Secretary’s attempt to recover funds based
on the States’ alleged violation of a rule that did not exist 
when the State accepted and spent the funds.  See 470 
U. S., at 640 (“New Jersey[,] when it applied for and re­
ceived Title I funds for the years 1970–1972[,] had no 
basis to believe that the propriety of the expenditures
would be judged by any standards other than the ones in
effect at the time.” (citing Pennhurst, 451 U. S., at 17, 24– 
25; emphasis added)).

When amendment of an existing grant program has no

such retroactive effect, however, we have upheld Congress’ 
instruction.  In Bennett v. Kentucky Dept. of Ed., 470 U. S. 
656 (1985), the Secretary sued to recapture Title I funds
based on the Commonwealth’s 1974 violation of a spend­
ing condition Congress added to Title I in 1970.  Rejecting
Kentucky’s argument pinned to Pennhurst, we held that 

—————— 

21 

THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE observes that “Spending Clause legislation

[i]s much in the nature of a contract.”  Ante, at 46 (internal quotation 

marks omitted).  See also post, at 33 (joint opinion of SCALIA, KENNEDY, 

THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ.) (same).  But the Court previously has rec- 
ognized that “[u]nlike normal contractual undertakings, federal grant 

programs originate in and remain governed by statutory provisions

expressing the judgment of Congress concerning desirable public 
policy.”  Bennett v. Kentucky Dept. of Ed., 470 U. S. 656, 669 (1985). 

22

Title I of the Elementary and Secondary Education Act of 1965 

provided federal grants to finance supplemental educational programs
in school districts with high concentrations of children from low-income

families.  See Bennett v. New Jersey, 470 U. S. 632, 634–635 (1985) 
(citing Pub. L. No. 89–10, 79 Stat. 27). 

background image 54 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

the Commonwealth suffered no surprise after accepting
the federal funds.  Kentucky was therefore obliged to re- 
turn the money.  470 U. S., at 665–666, 673–674.  The 
conditions imposed were to be assessed as of 1974, in light 
of “the legal requirements in place when the grants were
made,” id., at 670, not as of 1965, when Title I was origi­
nally enacted.

As these decisions show, Pennhurst’s rule demands that 

conditions on federal funds be unambiguously clear at the 
time a State receives and uses the money—not at the time,
perhaps years earlier, when Congress passed the law 
establishing the program.  See also Dole, 483 U. S., at 208 
(finding  Pennhurst  satisfied based on the clarity of the 
Federal Aid Highway Act as amended in 1984, without 
looking back to 1956, the year of the Act’s adoption). 

In any event, from the start, the Medicaid Act put

States on notice that the program could be changed: “The
right to alter, amend, or repeal any provision of [Medi­
caid],” the statute has read since 1965, “is hereby reserved 
to the Congress.”  42 U. S. C. §1304.  The “effect of these 
few simple words” has long been settled.  See National 
Railroad Passenger Corporation
 v. Atchison, T. & S. F. R. 
Co.
, 470 U. S. 451, 467–468, n. 22 (1985) (citing Sinking 
Fund Cases
, 99 U. S. 700, 720 (1879)).  By reserving the
right to “alter, amend, [or] repeal” a spending program,
Congress “has given special notice of its intention to retain 
. . . full and complete power to make such alterations and
amendments . . . as come within the just scope of legisla­
tive power.”  Id., at 720. 

Our decision in Bowen v. Public Agencies Opposed to 

Social Security Entrapment, 477 U. S. 41, 51–52 (1986), is 
guiding here.  As enacted in 1935, the Social Security Act 
did not cover state employees.  Id., at 44.  In response to
pressure from States that wanted coverage for their em­
ployees, Congress, in 1950, amended the Act to allow 
States to opt into the program.  Id., at 45.  The statutory 

background image 55 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

provision giving States this option expressly permitted 
them to withdraw from the program.  Ibid. 

Beginning in the late 1970’s, States increasingly exer­

cised the option to withdraw.  Id., at 46.  Concerned that 
withdrawals were threatening the integrity of Social 
Security, Congress repealed the termination provision.
Congress thereby changed Social Security from a program
voluntary for the States to one from which they could not 
escape.  Id.,  at 48.  California objected, arguing that the 
change impermissibly deprived it of a right to withdraw
from Social Security.  Id., at 49–50.  We unanimously 
rejected California’s argument.  Id., at 51–53.  By includ­
ing in the Act “a clause expressly reserving to it ‘[t]he 
right to alter, amend, or repeal any provision’ of the Act,” 
we held, Congress put States on notice that the Act 
“created no contractual rights.”  Id., at 51–52.  The States 
therefore had no law-based ground on which to complain
about the amendment, despite the significant character of 
the change.

THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE nevertheless would rewrite §1304

to countenance only the “right to alter somewhat,” or 
“amend, but not too much.”  Congress, however, did not so 
qualify §1304.  Indeed, Congress retained discretion to 
“repeal” Medicaid, wiping it out entirely.  Cf. Delta Air 
Lines, Inc.
 v. August, 450 U. S. 346, 368 (1981) (Rehnquist,
J., dissenting) (invoking “the common-sense maxim that 
the greater includes the lesser”).  As Bowen  indicates, no 
State could reasonably have read §1304 as reserving to
Congress authority to make adjustments only if modestly 
sized. 

In fact, no State proceeded on that understanding.  In com­

pliance with Medicaid regulations, each State expressly
undertook to abide by future Medicaid changes.  See 42 
CFR §430.12©(1) (2011) (“The [state Medicaid] plan must
provide that it will be amended whenever necessary to
reflect . . . [c]hanges in Federal law, regulations, policy 

background image 56 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

interpretations, or court decisions.”).  Whenever a State 
notifies the Federal Government of a change in its own 
Medicaid program, the State certifies both that it knows
the federally set terms of participation may change, and 
that it will abide by those changes as a condition of con­
tinued participation.  See, e.g., Florida Agency for Health
Care Admin., State Plan Under Title XIX of the Social 
Security Act Medical Assistance Program §7.1, p. 86 (Oct.
6, 1992).

THE CHIEF JUSTICE insists that the most recent expan­

sion, in contrast to its predecessors, “accomplishes a shift
in kind, not merely degree.”  Ante, at 53.  But why was 
Medicaid altered only in degree, not in kind, when Con­
gress required States to cover millions of children and 
pregnant women?  See supra, at 41–42.  Congress did not 
“merely alte[r] and expan[d] the boundaries of ” the Aid to
Families with Dependent Children program.  But see ante
at 53–55.  Rather, Congress required participating States
to provide coverage tied to the federal poverty level (as it
later did in the ACA), rather than to the AFDC program. 
See Brief for National Health Law Program et al. as Amici 
Curiae
 16–18.  In short, given §1304, this Court’s con­
struction of §1304’s language in Bowen, and the enlarge­
ment of Medicaid in the years since 1965,23 a State would 
be hard put to complain that it lacked fair notice when,
in 2010, Congress altered Medicaid to embrace a larger
portion of the Nation’s poor. 

THE CHIEF JUSTICE ultimately asks whether “the finan­

—————— 

23

Note, in this regard, the extension of Social Security, which began

in 1935 as an old-age pension program, then expanded to include sur- 
vivor benefits in 1939 and disability benefits in 1956.  See Social 

Security Act, ch. 531, 49 Stat. 622–625; Social Security Act Amend­

ments of 1939, 53 Stat. 1364–1365; Social Security Amendments of
1956, ch. 836,  §103, 70 Stat. 815–816. 

background image 57 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

cial inducement offered by Congress . . . pass[ed] the point 
at which pressure turns into compulsion.”  Ante, at 50 
(internal quotation marks omitted).  The financial in­
ducement Congress employed here, he concludes, crosses 
that threshold: The threatened withholding of “existing 
Medicaid funds” is “a gun to the head” that forces States to
acquiesce.  Ante, at 50–51 (citing 42 U. S. C. §1396c).24

 THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE sees no need to “fix the outermost 

line,” Steward Machine, 301 U. S., at 591, “where persua­
sion gives way to coercion,” ante, at 55.  Neither do the 
joint dissenters.  See post, at 36, 38.25  Notably, the deci­
—————— 

24

The joint dissenters, for their part, would make this the entire in­

quiry.  “[I]f States really have no choice other than to accept the pack­

age,” they assert, “the offer is coercive.”  Post, at 35.  THE CHIEF JUSTICE 

recognizes Congress’ authority to construct a single federal program 
and “condition the receipt of funds on the States’ complying with

restrictions on the use of those funds.”  Ante, at 50.  For the joint

dissenters, however, all that matters, it appears, is whether States can 
resist the temptation of a given federal grant.  Post, at 35.  On this 

logic, any federal spending program, sufficiently large and well-funded, 
would be unconstitutional.  The joint dissenters point to smaller pro­

grams States might have the will to refuse.  See post, at 40–41 (elemen­

tary and secondary education).  But how is a court to judge whether
“only  6.6% of all state expenditures,” post,  at 41, is an amount States 

could or would do without? 

Speculations of this genre are characteristic of the joint dissent.  See, 

e.g., post, at 35 (“it may  be state officials who will bear the brunt of 

public disapproval” for joint federal-state endeavors); ibid., (“federal

officials  . . .  may  remain insulated from the electoral ramifications of 
their decision”); post, at 37 (“a heavy federal tax . . . levied to support a

federal program that offers large grants to the States . . . may, as a 
practical matter, [leave States] unable to refuse to participate”); ibid. 

(withdrawal from a federal program “would likely force the State to 

impose a huge tax increase”); post, at 46 (state share of ACA expansion 
costs “may increase in the future”) (all emphasis added; some internal

quotation marks omitted).  The joint dissenters are long on conjecture

and short on real-world examples. 

25

The joint dissenters also rely heavily on Congress’ perceived intent

to coerce the States.  Post, at 42–46; see, e.g., post, at 42 (“In crafting the
ACA, Congress clearly expressed its informed view that no State could 

background image 58 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

sion on which they rely, Steward Machine, found the 
statute at issue inside the line, “wherever the line may 
be.”  301 U. S., at 591. 

When future Spending Clause challenges arrive, as they

likely will in the wake of today’s decision, how will liti­
gants and judges assess whether “a State has a legitimate 
choice whether to accept the federal conditions in ex­
change for federal funds”?  Ante, at 48.  Are courts to 
measure the number of dollars the Federal Government 
might withhold for noncompliance?  The portion of the
State’s budget at stake?  And which State’s—or States’— 
budget is determinative: the lead plaintiff, all challenging 
States (26 in this case, many with quite different fiscal
situations), or some national median?  Does it matter that
Florida, unlike most States, imposes no state income tax,
and therefore might be able to replace foregone federal 
funds with new state revenue?26  Or that the coercion state 
—————— 
possibly refuse the offer that the ACA extends.”).  We should not lightly
ascribe to Congress an intent to violate the Constitution (at least as my

colleagues read it).  This is particularly true when the ACA could just

as well be comprehended as demonstrating Congress’ mere expectation, 
in light of the uniformity of past participation and the generosity of the

federal contribution, that States would not withdraw.  Cf. South Dakota 

v. Dole, 483 U. S. 203, 211 (1987) (“We cannot conclude . . . that a con­
ditional grant of federal money . . . is unconstitutional simply by

reason of its success in achieving the congressional objective.”). 

26

Federal taxation of a State’s citizens, according to the joint dissent­

ers, may diminish a State’s ability to raise new revenue.  This, in turn, 

could limit a State’s capacity to replace a federal program with an

“equivalent” state-funded analog.  Post, at 40.  But it cannot be true 
that “the amount of the federal taxes extracted from the taxpayers of a

State to pay for the program in question is relevant in determining 

whether there is impermissible coercion.”  Post, at 37.  When the 
United States Government taxes United States citizens, it taxes them 

“in their individual capacities” as “the people of America”—not as

residents of a particular State.  See U. S. Term Limits, Inc. v. Thornton
514 U. S. 779, 839 (1995) (KENNEDY, J., concurring).  That is because 

the “Framers split the atom of sovereignty[,] . . . establishing two orders
of government”—“one state and one federal”—“each with its own direct 

background image 59 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

officials in fact fear is punishment at the ballot box for 
turning down a politically popular federal grant? 

The coercion inquiry, therefore, appears to involve polit- 

ical judgments that defy judicial calculation.  See Baker 
v.  Carr, 369 U. S. 186, 217 (1962).  Even commentators 
sympathetic to robust enforcement of Dole’s limitations, 
see  supra, at 46, have concluded that conceptions of 
“impermissible coercion” premised on States’ perceived 
inability to decline federal funds “are just too amorphous
to be judicially administrable.”  Baker & Berman, Getting 
off the Dole, 78 Ind. L. J. 459, 521, 522, n. 307 (2003) 
(citing, e.g., Scalia, The Rule of Law as a Law of Rules, 56 
U. Chi. L. Rev. 1175 (1989)).

At bottom, my colleagues’ position is that the States’ 

reliance on federal funds limits Congress’ authority to
alter its spending programs.  This gets things backwards: 
Congress, not the States, is tasked with spending federal 
money in service of the general welfare.  And each succes­
sive Congress is empowered to appropriate funds as it sees
fit.  When the 110th Congress reached a conclusion about
Medicaid funds that differed from its predecessors’ view,
it abridged no State’s right to “existing,” or “pre-existing,”
funds.  But see ante, at 51–52; post, at 47–48 (joint opinion
of SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ.).  For, in 

—————— 
relationship” to the people.  Id., at 838. 

A State therefore has no claim on the money its residents pay in

federal taxes, and federal “spending programs need not help people in
all states in the same measure.”  See Brief for David Satcher et al. as 

Amici Curiae 19.  In 2004, for example, New Jersey received 55 cents 

in federal spending for every dollar its residents paid to the Federal
Government in taxes, while Mississippi received $1.77 per tax dollar

paid.  C. Dubay, Tax Foundation, Federal Tax Burdens and Expendi­

tures by State: Which States Gain Most from Federal Fiscal Opera­
tions?  2 (Mar. 2006).  Thus no constitutional problem was created when

Arizona declined for 16 years to participate in Medicaid, even though 

its residents’ tax dollars financed Medicaid programs in every other 
State. 

background image 60 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

fact, there are no such funds.  There is only money States 
anticipate receiving from future Congresses. 

Congress has delegated to the Secretary of Health and

Human Services the authority to withhold, in whole or 
in part, federal Medicaid funds from States that fail to 
comply with the Medicaid Act as originally composed and as
subsequently amended.  42 U. S. C. §1396c.27  THE CHIEF 
JUSTICE, however, holds that the Constitution precludes 
the Secretary from withholding “existing” Medicaid funds
based on States’ refusal to comply with the expanded Medi­
caid program.  Ante, at 55.  For the foregoing reasons, I 
disagree that any such withholding would violate the
Spending Clause.  Accordingly, I would affirm the decision 
of the Court of Appeals for the Eleventh Circuit in this
regard.

But in view of THE CHIEF JUSTICE’s disposition, I agree

with him that the Medicaid Act’s severability clause de­
termines the appropriate remedy.  That clause provides
that “[i]f any provision of [the Medicaid Act], or the appli­
cation thereof to any person or circumstance, is held in- 
valid, the remainder of the chapter, and the application of
such provision to other persons or circumstances shall not
be affected thereby.”  42 U. S. C. §1303. 

The Court does not strike down any provision of the 

—————— 

27

As THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE observes, the Secretary is authorized to

withhold all of a State’s Medicaid funding.  See ante, at 51.  But total 
withdrawal is what the Secretary may, not must, do.  She has discre­

tion to withhold only a portion of the Medicaid funds otherwise due a 
noncompliant State.  See §1396c; cf. 45 CFR §80.10(f) (2011) (Secretary 

may enforce Title VI’s nondiscrimination requirement through “refusal 

to grant or continue Federal financial assistance, in whole or in part.” 
(emphasis added)).  The Secretary, it is worth noting, may herself 

experience political pressures, which would make her all the more

reluctant to cut off funds Congress has appropriated for a State’s needy 
citizens. 

background image 61 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

Opinion of GINSBURG, J. 

ACA.  It prohibits only the “application” of the Secretary’s 
authority to withhold Medicaid funds from States that 
decline to conform their Medicaid plans to the ACA’s
requirements.  Thus the ACA’s authorization of funds to 
finance the expansion remains intact, and the Secretary’s
authority to withhold funds for reasons other than non­
compliance with the expansion remains unaffected. 

Even absent §1303’s command, we would have no war­

rant to invalidate the Medicaid expansion, contra post, at 
46–48 (joint opinion of SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and 
ALITO, JJ.), not to mention the entire ACA, post, at 49–64 
(same).  For when a court confronts an unconstitutional 
statute, its endeavor must be to conserve, not destroy,
the legislature’s dominant objective.  See, e.g., Ayotte v. 
Planned Parenthood of Northern New Eng., 546 U. S. 320, 
328–330 (2006).  In this case, that objective was to in­
crease access to health care for the poor by increasing the 
States’ access to federal funds.  THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE is 
undoubtedly right to conclude that Congress may offer 
States funds “to expand the availability of health care, and 
requir[e] that States accepting such funds comply with the 
conditions on their use.”  Ante, at 55.  I therefore concur 
in the judgment with respect to Part IV–B of THE  CHIEF 
JUSTICE’s opinion. 

*  *  * 

For the reasons stated, I agree with THE CHIEF JUSTICE 

that, as to the validity of the minimum coverage provi­
sion, the judgment of the Court of Appeals for the Eleventh
Circuit should be reversed.  In my view, the provision en- 
counters no constitutional obstruction.  Further, I would 
uphold the Eleventh Circuit’s decision that the Medicaid 
expansion is within Congress’ spending power. 

background image _________________ 

_________________ 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES 

Nos. 11–393, 11–398 and 11–400 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

BUSINESS, ET AL., PETITIONERS 

11–393 

v. 

KATHLEEN SEBELIUS, SECRETARY OF HEALTH 

AND HUMAN SERVICES, ET AL. 

DEPARTMENT OF HEALTH AND HUMAN 

SERVICES, ET AL., PETITIONERS 

11–398 

v. 

FLORIDA ET AL. 

11–400 

FLORIDA, ET AL., PETITIONERS 

v. 

DEPARTMENT OF HEALTH AND 

HUMAN SERVICES ET AL. 

ON WRITS OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF 

APPEALS FOR THE ELEVENTH CIRCUIT 

[June 28, 2012]

 JUSTICE  SCALIA,  JUSTICE  KENNEDY,  JUSTICE  THOMAS, 

and JUSTICE ALITO, dissenting. 

Congress has set out to remedy the problem that the 

best health care is beyond the reach of many Americans 
who cannot afford it.  It can assuredly do that, by exercis-
ing the powers accorded to it under the Constitution.  The 
question in this case, however, is whether the complex 
structures and provisions of the Patient Protection and
Affordable Care Act (Affordable Care Act or ACA) go be- 
yond those powers.  We conclude that they do.

This case is in one respect difficult: it presents two 

background image

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

questions of first impression.  The first of those is whether 
failure to engage in economic activity (the purchase of
health insurance) is subject to regulation under the Com-
merce Clause.  Failure to act does result in an effect 
on commerce, and hence might be said to come under 
this Court’s “affecting commerce” criterion of Commerce 
Clause jurisprudence.  But in none of its decisions has this 
Court extended the Clause that far.  The second question
is whether the congressional power to tax and spend, 
U. S. Const., Art. I, §8, cl. 1, permits the conditioning of
a State’s continued receipt of all funds under a massive 
state-administered federal welfare program upon its ac-
ceptance of an expansion to that program.  Several of our 
opinions have suggested that the power to tax and spend 
cannot be used to coerce state administration of a federal 
program, but we have never found a law enacted under 
the spending power to be coercive.  Those questions are 
difficult. 

The case is easy and straightforward, however, in an-

other respect.  What is absolutely clear, affirmed by the
text of the 1789 Constitution, by the Tenth Amendment
ratified in 1791, and by innumerable cases of ours in the 
220 years since, is that there are structural limits upon 
federal power—upon what it can prescribe with respect to 
private conduct, and upon what it can impose upon the
sovereign States.  Whatever may be the conceptual limits
upon the Commerce Clause and upon the power to tax
and spend, they cannot be such as will enable the Federal 
Government to regulate all private conduct and to com-
pel the States to function as administrators of federal 
programs.

That clear principle carries the day here.  The striking 

case of Wickard v. Filburn, 317 U. S. 111 (1942), which
held that the economic activity of growing wheat, even 
for one’s own consumption, affected commerce sufficiently
that it could be regulated, always has been regarded as 

background image

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

the ne plus ultra of expansive Commerce Clause jurispru-
dence.  To go beyond that, and to say the failure to grow 
wheat (which is not  an economic activity, or any activity
at all) nonetheless affects commerce and therefore can be
federally regulated, is to make mere breathing in and out 
the basis for federal prescription and to extend federal 
power to virtually all human activity.

As for the constitutional power to tax and spend for 

the general welfare: The Court has long since expanded
that beyond (what Madison thought it meant) taxing and 
spending for those aspects of the general welfare that were
within the Federal Government’s enumerated powers, 
see  United States v. Butler, 297 U. S. 1, 65–66 (1936).
Thus, we now have sizable federal Departments devoted 
to subjects not mentioned among Congress’ enumerated
powers, and only marginally related to commerce: the De-
partment of Education, the Department of Health and 
Human Services, the Department of Housing and Urban
Development.  The principal practical obstacle that pre-
vents Congress from using the tax-and-spend power to 
assume all the general-welfare responsibilities tradition-
ally exercised by the States is the sheer impossibility of 
managing a Federal Government large enough to adminis-
ter such a system.  That obstacle can be overcome by
granting funds to the States, allowing them to administer 
the program.  That is fair and constitutional enough when
the States freely agree to have their powers employed and
their employees enlisted in the federal scheme.  But it is a 
blatant violation of the constitutional structure when the 
States have no choice. 

The Act before us here exceeds federal power both in 

mandating the purchase of health insurance and in deny-
ing nonconsenting States all Medicaid funding.  These 
parts of the Act are central to its design and operation, 
and all the Act’s other provisions would not have been
enacted without them.  In our view it must follow that the 

background image

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

entire statute is inoperative. 

The Individual Mandate 

Article I, §8, of the Constitution gives Congress the 

power to “regulate Commerce . . . among the several 
States.”  The Individual Mandate in the Act commands 
that every “applicable individual shall for each month 
beginning after 2013 ensure that the individual, and any 
dependent of the individual who is an applicable individ-
ual, is covered under minimum essential coverage.”  26 
U. S. C. §5000A(a) (2006 ed., Supp. IV).  If this provision 
“regulates” anything, it is the failure to maintain mini-
mum essential coverage.  One might argue that it regu-
lates that failure by requiring it to be accompanied by 
payment of a penalty.  But that failure—that abstention 
from commerce—is not “Commerce.”  To be sure, purchas-
ing
 insurance is ”Commerce”; but one does not regulate 
commerce that does not exist by compelling its existence. 

In Gibbons v. Ogden, 9 Wheat. 1, 196 (1824), Chief 

Justice Marshall wrote that the power to regulate com-
merce is the power “to prescribe the rule by which
commerce is to be governed.”  That understanding is con- 
sistent with the original meaning of “regulate” at the time 
of the Constitution’s ratification, when “to regulate” meant
“[t]o adjust by rule, method or established mode,” 2 N.
Webster, An American Dictionary of the English Lan-
guage (1828); “[t]o adjust by rule or method,” 2 S. Johnson,
A Dictionary of the English Language (7th ed. 1785); “[t]o
adjust, to direct according to rule,” 2 J. Ash, New and 
Complete Dictionary of the English Language (1775); “to
put in order, set to rights, govern or keep in order,” T.
Dyche & W. Pardon, A New General English Dictionary 

background image

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

(16th ed. 1777).1  It can mean to direct the manner of 
something but not to direct that something come into 
being.  There is no instance in which this Court or Con-
gress (or anyone else, to our knowledge) has used “regulate”
in that peculiar fashion.  If the word bore that meaning, 
Congress’ authority “[t]o make Rules for the Govern-
ment and Regulation of the land and naval Forces,” U. S. 
Const., Art. I, §8, cl. 14, would have made superfluous 
the later provision for authority “[t]o raise and support
Armies,”  id., §8, cl. 12, and “[t]o provide and maintain a 
Navy,” id., §8, cl. 13.

We do not doubt that the buying and selling of health 

insurance contracts is commerce generally subject to 
federal regulation.  But when Congress provides that 
(nearly) all citizens must buy an insurance contract, it 
goes beyond “adjust[ing] by rule or method,” Johnson, 
supra, or “direct[ing] according to rule,” Ash, supra; it 
directs the creation of commerce. 

In response, the Government offers two theories as to 

why the Individual Mandate is nevertheless constitu-
tional.  Neither theory suffices to sustain its validity. 

First, the Government submits that §5000A is “integral 

to the Affordable Care Act’s insurance reforms” and “nec-
essary to make effective the Act’s core reforms.”  Brief 
for Petitioners in No. 11–398 (Minimum Coverage Provi-
sion) 24 (hereinafter Petitioners’ Minimum Coverage Brief). 
Congress included a “finding” to similar effect in the Act 

—————— 

1

The most authoritative legal dictionaries of the founding era lack

any definition for “regulate” or “regulation,” suggesting that the term
bears its ordinary meaning (rather than some specialized legal mean-

ing) in the constitutional text.  See R. Burn, A New Law Dictionary 281

(1792); G. Jacob, A New Law Dictionary (10th ed. 1782); 2 T. Cunning-
ham, A New and Complete Law Dictionary (2d ed. 1771). 

background image

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

itself.  See 42 U. S. C. §18091(2)(H). 

As discussed in more detail in Part V, infra, the Act 

contains numerous health insurance reforms, but most 
notable for present purposes are the “guaranteed issue” 
and “community rating” provisions, §§300gg to 300gg–4.
The former provides that, with a few exceptions, “each
health insurance issuer that offers health insurance cov-
erage in the individual or group market in a State must 
accept every employer and individual in the State that 
applies for such coverage.”  §300gg–1(a).  That is, an in-
surer may not deny coverage on the basis of, among other 
things, any pre-existing medical condition that the appli-
cant may have, and the resulting insurance must cover 
that condition.  See §300gg–3.

Under ordinary circumstances, of course, insurers would

respond by charging high premiums to individuals with
pre-existing conditions.  The Act seeks to prevent this 
through the community-rating provision.  Simply put, the
community-rating provision requires insurers to calculate 
an individual’s insurance premium based on only four
factors: (i) whether the individual’s plan covers just
the individual or his family also, (ii) the “rating area” in
which the individual lives, (iii) the individual’s age, and
(iv) whether the individual uses tobacco.  §300gg(a)(1)(A).
Aside from the rough proxies of age and tobacco use (and 
possibly rating area), the Act does not allow an insurer to
factor the individual’s health characteristics into the price
of his insurance premium.  This creates a new incentive 
for young and healthy individuals without pre-existing 
conditions.  The insurance premiums for those in this
group will not reflect their own low actuarial risks but will 
subsidize insurance for others in the pool.  Many of them 
may decide that purchasing health insurance is not an eco-
nomically sound decision—especially since the guaranteed-
issue provision will enable them to purchase it at the 
same cost in later years and even if they have developed a 

background image

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

pre-existing condition.  But without the contribution of 
above-risk premiums from the young and healthy, the 
community-rating provision will not enable insurers to 
take on high-risk individuals without a massive increase 
in premiums.

The Government presents the Individual Mandate as a

unique feature of a complicated regulatory scheme govern-
ing many parties with countervailing incentives that must
be carefully balanced.  Congress has imposed an extensive 
set of regulations on the health insurance industry, and
compliance with those regulations will likely cost the in- 
dustry a great deal.  If the industry does not respond by
increasing premiums, it is not likely to survive.  And if 
the industry does increase premiums, then there is a seri-
ous risk that its products—insurance plans—will become
economically undesirable for many and prohibitively ex- 
pensive for the rest.

This is not a dilemma unique to regulation of the health-

insurance industry.  Government regulation typically
imposes costs on the regulated industry—especially regu-
lation that prohibits economic behavior in which most 
market participants are already engaging, such as “piec-
ing out” the market by selling the product to different 
classes of people at different prices (in the present context, 
providing much lower insurance rates to young and 
healthy buyers).  And many industries so regulated face
the reality that, without an artificial increase in demand,
they cannot continue on.  When Congress is regulating 
these industries directly, it enjoys the broad power to
enact “ ‘all appropriate legislation’ ” to “ ‘protec[t]’ ” and
“ ‘advanc[e]’ ” commerce, NLRB v. Jones & Laughlin Steel 
Corp.
, 301 U. S. 1, 36–37 (1937) (quoting The Daniel Ball
10 Wall. 557, 564 (1871)).  Thus, Congress might protect 
the imperiled industry by prohibiting low-cost competition, 
or by according it preferential tax treatment, or even by 
granting it a direct subsidy. 

background image

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

Here, however, Congress has impressed into service

third parties, healthy individuals who could be but are not 
customers of the relevant industry, to offset the undesir-
able consequences of the regulation.  Congress’ desire to 
force these individuals to purchase insurance is motivated
by the fact that they are further removed from the market
than unhealthy individuals with pre-existing conditions, 
because they are less likely to need extensive care in 
the near future.  If Congress can reach out and command 
even those furthest removed from an interstate market to 
participate in the market, then the Commerce Clause 
becomes a font of unlimited power, or in Hamilton’s words, 
“the hideous monster whose devouring jaws . . . spare 
neither sex nor age, nor high nor low, nor sacred nor pro-
fane.”  The Federalist No. 33, p. 202 (C. Rossiter ed. 1961).

At the outer edge of the commerce power, this Court has

insisted on careful scrutiny of regulations that do not
act directly on an interstate market or its participants.  In 
New York v. United States, 505 U. S. 144 (1992), we held 
that Congress could not, in an effort to regulate the dis-
posal of radioactive waste produced in several different
industries, order the States to take title to that waste. 
Id., at 174–177.  In Printz v. United States, 521 U. S. 
898 (1997), we held that Congress could not, in an effort to 
regulate the distribution of firearms in the interstate mar-
ket, compel state law-enforcement officials to perform 
background checks.  Id., at 933–935.  In United States v. 
Lopez, 514 U. S. 549 (1995), we held that Congress could 
not, as a means of fostering an educated interstate labor 
market through the protection of schools, ban the posses-
sion of a firearm within a school zone.  Id., at 559–563. 
And in United States v. Morrison, 529 U. S. 598 (2000), we
held that Congress could not, in an effort to ensure the full
participation of women in the interstate economy, subject
private individuals and companies to suit for gender-
motivated violent torts.  Id., at 609–619.  The lesson of 

background image

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

these cases is that the Commerce Clause, even when sup- 
plemented by the Necessary and Proper Clause, is not 
carte blanche for doing whatever will help achieve the 
ends Congress seeks by the regulation of commerce.  And 
the last two of these cases show that the scope of the 
Necessary and Proper Clause is exceeded not only when 
the congressional action directly violates the sovereignty
of the States but also when it violates the background 
principle of enumerated (and hence limited) federal power. 

The case upon which the Government principally relies 

to sustain the Individual Mandate under the Necessary
and Proper Clause is Gonzales v. Raich, 545 U. S. 1 (2005).
That case held that Congress could, in an effort to restrain
the interstate market in marijuana, ban the local cultiva-
tion and possession of that drug.  Id., at 15–22.  Raich 
is no precedent for what Congress has done here.  That 
case’s prohibition of growing (cf. Wickard, 317 U. S. 111),
and of possession (cf. innumerable federal statutes) did not
represent the expansion of the federal power to direct into
a broad new field.  The mandating of economic activity 
does, and since it is a field so limitless that it converts the 
Commerce Clause into a general authority to direct the
economy, that mandating is not “consist[ent] with the
letter and spirit of the constitution.”  McCulloch v. Mary-
land
, 4 Wheat. 316, 421 (1819). 

Moreover, Raich is far different from the Individual 

Mandate in another respect.  The Court’s opinion in Raich 
pointed out that the growing and possession prohibitions 
were the only practicable way of enabling the prohibition
of interstate traffic in marijuana to be effectively enforced.
545 U. S., at 22.  See also Shreveport Rate Cases, 234 U. S. 
342 (1914) (Necessary and Proper Clause allows regula-
tions of intrastate transactions if necessary to the regula-
tion of an interstate market).  Intrastate marijuana could
no more be distinguished from interstate marijuana than,
for example, endangered-species trophies obtained before 

background image 10 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

the species was federally protected can be distinguished 
from trophies obtained afterwards—which made it neces-
sary and proper to prohibit the sale of all such trophies, 
see Andrus v. Allard, 444 U. S. 51 (1979). 

With the present statute, by contrast, there are many

ways other than this unprecedented Individual Mandate 
by which the regulatory scheme’s goals of reducing insur-
ance premiums and ensuring the profitability of insurers
could be achieved.  For instance, those who did not pur-
chase insurance could be subjected to a surcharge when
they do enter the health insurance system.  Or they could
be denied a full income tax credit given to those who do
purchase the insurance. 

The Government was invited, at oral argument, to

suggest what federal controls over private conduct (other
than those explicitly prohibited by the Bill of Rights or 
other constitutional controls) could not  be justified as 
necessary and proper for the carrying out of a general 
regulatory scheme.  See Tr. of Oral Arg. 27–30, 43–45 
(Mar. 27, 2012).  It was unable to name any.  As we said at 
the outset, whereas the precise scope of the Commerce 
Clause and the Necessary and Proper Clause is uncertain,
the proposition that the Federal Government cannot do 
everything is a fundamental precept.  See Lopez, 514 U. S., 
at 564 (“[I]f we were to accept the Government’s argu-
ments, we are hard pressed to posit any activity by an in- 
dividual that Congress is without power to regulate”).
Section 5000A is defeated by that proposition. 

The Government’s second theory in support of the In-

dividual Mandate is that §5000A is valid because it is 
actually a “regulat[ion of] activities having a substantial 
relation to interstate commerce, . . . i.e., . . . activities that 
substantially affect interstate commerce.”  Id., at 558–559. 
See also Shreveport Rate Cases,  supra.  This argument 

background image 11 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

takes a few different forms, but the basic idea is that 
§5000A regulates “the way in which individuals finance 
their participation in the health-care market.”  Petitioners’ 
Minimum Coverage Brief 33 (emphasis added).  That is, 
the provision directs the manner in which individuals 
purchase health care services and related goods (directing 
that they be purchased through insurance) and is there-
fore a straightforward exercise of the commerce power. 

The primary problem with this argument is that §5000A 

does not apply only to persons who purchase all, or most, 
or even any, of the health care services or goods that the 
mandated insurance covers.  Indeed, the main objection 
many have to the Mandate is that they have no intention 
of purchasing most or even any of such goods or services 
and thus no need to buy insurance for those purchases. 
The Government responds that the health-care market 
involves “essentially universal participation,” id., at 35. 
The principal difficulty with this response is that it is, in 
the only relevant sense, not true.  It is true enough that 
everyone consumes “health care,” if the term is taken to 
include the purchase of a bottle of aspirin.  But the health 
care “market” that is the object of the Individual Mandate 
not only includes but principally consists of goods and 
services that the young people primarily affected by the 
Mandate  do not purchase.  They are quite simply not 
participants in that market, and cannot be made so (and 
thereby subjected to regulation) by the simple device of 
defining participants to include all those who will, later in 
their lifetime, probably purchase the goods or services 
covered by the mandated insurance.2  Such a definition of 
—————— 

JUSTICE  GINSBURG is therefore right to note that Congress is “not

mandating the purchase of a discrete, unwanted product.”  Ante, at 22 
(opinion concurring in part, concurring in judgment in part, and dis-

background image 12 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

market participants is unprecedented, and were it to be a 
premise for the exercise of national power, it would have 
no principled limits. 

In a variation on this attempted exercise of federal 

power, the Government points out that Congress in this 
Act has purported to regulate “economic and financial 
decision[s] to forego [sic] health insurance coverage and 
[to] attempt to self-insure,” 42 U. S. C. §18091(2)(A), since 
those decisions have “a substantial and deleterious effect 
on interstate commerce,” Petitioners’ Minimum Coverage 
Brief 34.  But as the discussion above makes clear, the 
decision to forgo participation in an interstate market is 
not itself commercial activity (or indeed any activity at all) 
within Congress’ power to regulate.  It is true that, at the 
end of the day, it is inevitable that each American will 
affect commerce and become a part of it, even if not by 
choice.  But if every person comes within the Commerce 
Clause power of Congress to regulate by the simple reason 
that he will one day engage in commerce, the idea of a 
limited Government power is at an end. 

Wickard  v. Filburn has been regarded as the most ex-

pansive assertion of the commerce power in our history.  A 
close second is Perez v. United States, 402 U. S. 146 (1971), 
which upheld a statute criminalizing the eminently local 
activity of loan-sharking.  Both of those cases, however, 

—————— 
senting in part).  Instead, it is mandating the purchase of an unwanted 

suite of products—e.g.,  physician office visits, emergency room visits,

hospital room and board, physical therapy, durable medical equipment,
mental health care, and substance abuse detoxification.  See Selected 

Medical Benefits: A Report from the Dept. of Labor to the Dept. of 

Health & Human Services (April 15, 2011) (reporting that over two-
thirds of private industry health plans cover these goods and services), 

online at http://www.bls.gov/ncs/ebs/sp/selmedbensreport.pdf (all Inter-

net materials as visited June 26, 2012, and available in Clerk of Court’s 
case file). 

background image 13 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

involved commercial activity.  To go beyond that, and to 
say that the failure to grow wheat or the refusal to make 
loans affects commerce, so that growing and lending can 
be federally compelled, is to extend federal power to virtu-
ally everything.  All of us consume food, and when we do 
so the Federal Government can prescribe what its quality 
must be and even how much we must pay.  But the mere 
fact that we all consume food and are thus, sooner or later, 
participants in the “market” for food, does not empower 
the Government to say when and what we will buy.  That 
is essentially what this Act seeks to do with respect to the 
purchase of health care.  It exceeds federal power. 

A few respectful responses to JUSTICE  GINSBURG’s dis-

sent on the issue of the Mandate are in order.  That dis-
sent duly recites the test of Commerce Clause power that
our opinions have applied, but disregards the premise the 
test contains.  It is true enough that Congress needs only a 
“ ‘rational basis’ for concluding that the regulated activity
substantially affects interstate commerce,” ante, at 15 (em-
phasis added).  But it must be activity  affecting com-
merce that is regulated, and not merely the failure to
engage in commerce.  And one is not now purchasing
the health care covered by the insurance mandate simply 
because one is likely to be purchasing it in the future.  Our 
test’s premise of regulated activity is not invented out of 
whole cloth, but rests upon the Constitution’s requirement
that it be commerce which is regulated.  If all inactivity 
affecting commerce is commerce, commerce is everything.
Ultimately the dissent is driven to saying that there is
really no difference between action and inaction, ante, at 
26, a proposition that has never recommended itself, 
neither to the law nor to common sense.  To say, for exam-
ple, that the inaction here consists of activity in “the self-
insurance market,” ibid., seems to us wordplay.  By parity 

background image 14 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

of reasoning the failure to buy a car can be called partici-
pation in the non-private-car-transportation market.  Com-
merce becomes everything.

The dissent claims that we “fai[l] to explain why the 

individual mandate threatens our constitutional order.” 
Ante, at 35.  But we have done so.  It threatens that order 
because it gives such an expansive meaning to the Com-
merce Clause that all private conduct (including failure to 
act) becomes subject to federal control, effectively destroy-
ing the Constitution’s division of governmental powers. 
Thus the dissent, on the theories proposed for the validity 
of the Mandate, would alter the accepted constitutional 
relation between the individual and the National Govern-
ment.  The dissent protests that the Necessary and Proper 
Clause has been held to include “the power to enact crimi-
nal laws, . . . the power to imprison, . . . and the power to 
create a national bank,” ante, at 34–35.  Is not the power 
to compel purchase of health insurance much lesser?  No, 
not if (unlike those other dispositions) its application rests 
upon a theory that everything is within federal control 
simply because it exists. 

The dissent’s exposition of the wonderful things the Fed- 

eral Government has achieved through exercise of its 
assigned powers, such as “the provision of old-age and 
survivors’ benefits” in the Social Security Act, ante, at 2, 
is quite beside the point.  The issue here is whether the 
federal government can impose the Individual Mandate 
through the Commerce Clause.  And the relevant history 
is not that Congress has achieved wide and wonderful 
results through the proper exercise of its assigned powers 
in the past, but that it has never before used the Com-
merce Clause to compel entry into commerce.3  The dissent 

—————— 

3

In its effort to show the contrary, JUSTICE GINSBURG’S dissent comes 

background image 15 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

treats the Constitution as though it is an enumeration of 
those problems that the Federal Government can ad-
dress—among which, it finds, is “the Nation’s course in 
the economic and social welfare realm,” ibid., and more 
specifically “the problem of the uninsured,” ante, at 7. 
The Constitution is not that.  It enumerates not federally 
soluble  problems, but federally available powers.  The 
Federal Government can address whatever problems it 
wants but can bring to their solution only those powers 
that the Constitution confers, among which is the power to 
regulate commerce.  None of our cases say anything else. 
Article I contains no whatever-it-takes-to-solve-a-national-
problem power. 

The dissent dismisses the conclusion that the power to 

compel entry into the health-insurance market would 
include the power to compel entry into the new-car or 
broccoli markets.  The latter purchasers, it says, “will be 
obliged to pay at the counter before receiving the vehicle 

—————— 
up with nothing more than two condemnation cases, which it says

demonstrate “Congress’ authority under the commerce power to compel

an ‘inactive’ landholder to submit to an unwanted sale.”  Ante,  at 24. 
Wrong on both scores.  As its name suggests, the condemnation power 

does  not  “compel”  anyone  to  do  anything.    It  acts  in rem, against the

property that is condemned, and is effective with or without a transfer
of title from the former owner.  More important, the power to condemn

for public use is a separate sovereign power, explicitly acknowledged in

the Fifth Amendment, which provides that “private property [shall not]
be taken for public use, without just compensation.”

Thus, the power to condemn tends to refute rather than support

the power to compel purchase of unwanted goods at a prescribed price:
The latter is rather like the power to condemn cash for public use.  If it 

existed, why would it not (like the condemnation power) be accompa-

nied by a requirement of fair compensation for the portion of the 
exacted price that exceeds the goods’ fair market value (here, the

difference between what the free market would charge for a health-

insurance policy on a young, healthy person with no pre-existing 
conditions, and the government-exacted community-rated premium)? 

background image 16 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

or nourishment,” whereas those refusing to purchase 
health-insurance will ultimately get treated anyway, at 
others’ expense.  Ante, at 21.  “[T]he unique attributes of 
the health-care market . . . give rise to a significant free-
riding problem that does not occur in other markets.” 
Ante, at 28.  And “a vegetable-purchase mandate” (or a 
car-purchase mandate) is not “likely to have a substantial 
effect on the health-care costs” borne by other Americans. 
Ante, at 29.  Those differences make a very good argument 
by the dissent’s own lights, since they show that the fail-
ure to purchase health insurance, unlike the failure to 
purchase cars or broccoli, creates a national, social-welfare 
problem that is (in the dissent’s view) included among the 
unenumerated “problems” that the Constitution author-
izes the Federal Government to solve.  But those differences 
do not show that the failure to enter the health-insurance 
market, unlike the failure to buy cars and broccoli, is 
an  activity  that Congress can “regulate.”  (Of course one 
day the failure of some of the public to purchase Amer-
ican cars may endanger the existence of domestic automo-
bile manufacturers; or the failure of some to eat broccoli 
may be found to deprive them of a newly discovered cancer-
fighting chemical which only that food contains, producing 
health-care costs that are a burden on the rest of us—in 
which case, under the theory of JUSTICE  GINSBURG’s dis-
sent, moving against those inactivities will also come 
within the Federal Government’s unenumerated problem-
solving powers.) 

II 

The Taxing Power 

As far as §5000A is concerned, we would stop there. 

Congress has attempted to regulate beyond the scope of its 

background image 17 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

Commerce Clause authority,4 and §5000A is therefore 
invalid.  The Government contends, however, as expressed 
in the caption to Part II of its brief, that “THE MINIMUM 
COVERAGE PROVISION IS INDEPENDENTLY AUTHORIZED BY 
CONGRESS

’S TAXING POWER.”  Petitioners’ Minimum Cov-

erage Brief 52.  The phrase “independently authorized” 
suggests the existence of a creature never hitherto seen 
in the United States Reports: A penalty for constitutional 
purposes that is also a tax for constitutional purposes.  In 
all our cases the two are mutually exclusive.  The provi-
sion challenged under the Constitution is either a penalty 
or else a tax.  Of course in many cases what was a regu-
latory mandate enforced by a penalty could have been 
imposed as a tax upon permissible action; or what was im- 
posed as a tax upon permissible action could have been a 
regulatory mandate enforced by a penalty.  But we know 
of no case, and the Government cites none, in which the 
imposition was, for constitutional purposes, both.5    The  
two are mutually exclusive.  Thus, what the Government’s 
caption should have read was “ALTERNATIVELY, THE 
MINIMUM COVERAGE PROVISION IS NOT A MANDATE

-WITH-

PENALTY BUT A TAX

.”  It is important to bear this in mind 

in evaluating the tax argument of the Government and of 
those who support it: The issue is not whether Congress 

—————— 

4

No one seriously contends that any of Congress’ other enumerated 

powers gives it the authority to enact §5000A as a regulation

5

Of course it can be both for statutory purposes, since Congress can 

define “tax” and “penalty” in its enactments any way it wishes.  That is 
why United States v. Sotelo, 436 U. S. 268 (1978), does not disprove our 

statement.  That case held that a “penalty” for willful failure to pay 

one’s taxes was included among the “taxes” made non-dischargeable 
under the Bankruptcy Code.  436 U. S., at 273–275.  Whether the 

“penalty” was a “tax” within the meaning of the Bankruptcy Code had 

absolutely no bearing on whether it escaped the constitutional limita-
tions on penalties. 

background image 18 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

had the power  to frame the minimum-coverage provision 
as a tax, but whether it did so. 

In answering that question we must, if “fairly possible,” 

Crowell v. Benson, 285 U. S. 22, 62 (1932), construe the 
provision to be a tax rather than a mandate-with-penalty, 
since that would render it constitutional rather than un- 
constitutional (ut res magis valeat quam pereat).  But we 
cannot rewrite the statute to be what it is not.  “‘ “[A]l- 
though this Court will often strain to construe legis- 
lation  so  as  to  save  it  against constitutional attack, it 
must not and will not carry this to the point of perverting 
the purpose of a statute . . .” or judicially rewriting it.’”  
Commodity Futures Trading Comm’n v. Schor, 478 U. S. 
833, 841 (1986) (quoting Aptheker v. Secretary of State
378 U. S. 500, 515 (1964), in turn quoting Scales v. United 
States
, 367 U. S. 203, 211 (1961)).  In this case, there is 
simply no way, “without doing violence to the fair meaning 
of the words used,” Grenada County Supervisors v. Brog-
den
, 112 U. S. 261, 269 (1884), to escape what Congress 
enacted: a mandate that individuals maintain minimum 
essential coverage, enforced by a penalty. 

Our cases establish a clear line between a tax and a 

penalty: “ ‘[A] tax is an enforced contribution to provide for

the support of government; a penalty . . . is an exaction 

imposed by statute as punishment for an unlawful act.’ ” 

United States v. Reorganized CF&I Fabricators of Utah, 

Inc., 518 U. S. 213, 224 (1996) (quoting United States v. La 

Franca, 282 U. S. 568, 572 (1931)).  In a few cases, this 

Court has held that a “tax” imposed upon private conduct 

was so onerous as to be in effect a penalty.  But we have 

never held—never—that a penalty imposed for violation of 

the law was so trivial as to be in effect a tax.  We have 

never held that any exaction imposed for violation of 

the law is an exercise of Congress’ taxing power—even

when the statute calls it a tax, much less when (as here)

the statute repeatedly calls it a penalty.  When an act 

background image 19 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

“adopt[s] the criteria of wrongdoing” and then imposes a

monetary penalty as the “principal consequence on those

who transgress its standard,” it creates a regulatory pen-

alty, not a tax.  Child Labor Tax Case, 259 U. S. 20, 38 

(1922). 

So the question is, quite simply, whether the exaction 

here is imposed for violation of the law.  It unquestion-
ably is.  The minimum-coverage provision is found in 26
U. S. C. §5000A, entitled “Requirement to maintain mini-
mum essential coverage.” (Emphasis added.)  It commands 
that every “applicable individual shall . . . ensure that the 
individual . . . is covered under minimum essential cover-
age.”  Ibid. (emphasis added).  And the immediately fol-
lowing provision states that, “[i]f . . . an applicable 
individual . . . fails to meet the requirement of subsection 
(a) . . . there is hereby imposed . . . a penalty.”  §5000A(b)
(emphasis added).  And several of Congress’ legislative
“findings” with regard to §5000A confirm that it sets forth
a legal requirement and constitutes the assertion of regu-
latory power, not mere taxing power.  See 42 U. S. C. 
§18091(2)(A) (“The requirement regulates activity . . .”);
§18091(2)(C) (“The requirement . . . will add millions of 
new consumers to the health insurance market . . .”); 
§18091(2)(D) (“The requirement achieves near-universal 
coverage”); §18091(2)(H) (“The requirement is an essential 
part of this larger regulation of economic activity, and the 
absence of the requirement would undercut Federal regu-
lation of the health insurance market”); §18091(3) (“[T]he 
Supreme Court of the United States ruled that insurance
is interstate commerce subject to Federal regulation”). 

The Government and those who support its view on the 

tax point rely on New York v. United States, 505 U. S. 144, 
to justify reading “shall” to mean “may.”  The “shall” in 
that case was contained in an introductory provision—a
recital that provided for no legal consequences—which 
said that “[e]ach State shall be responsible for providing 

background image 20 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

. . . for the disposal of . . . low-level radioactive waste.”  42 
U. S. C. §2021c(a)(1)(A).  The Court did not hold that 
“shall” could be construed to mean “may,” but rather that
this preliminary provision could not impose upon the oper- 
ative provisions of the Act a mandate that they did not 
contain: “We . . . decline petitioners’ invitation to con- 
strue §2021c(a)(1)(A), alone and in isolation, as a com-
mand to the States independent of the remainder of the
Act.”  New York, 505 U. S., at 170.  Our opinion then
proceeded to “consider each [of the three operative provi-
sions] in turn.”  Ibid.  Here the mandate—the “shall”—is 
contained not in an inoperative preliminary recital, but in
the dispositive operative provision itself.  New York pro-
vides no support for reading it to be permissive. 

Quite separately, the fact that Congress (in its own

words) “imposed . . . a penalty,” 26 U. S. C. §5000A(b)(1),
for failure to buy insurance is alone sufficient to render
that failure unlawful.  It is one of the canons of interpreta-
tion that a statute that penalizes an act makes it unlaw-
ful: “[W]here the statute inflicts a penalty for doing an act, 
although the act itself is not expressly prohibited, yet to do
the act is unlawful, because it cannot be supposed that the
Legislature intended that a penalty should be inflicted for 
a lawful act.”  Powhatan Steamboat Co. v. Appomattox R. 
Co.
, 24 How. 247, 252 (1861).  Or in the words of Chancel-
lor Kent: “If a statute inflicts a penalty for doing an act,
the penalty implies a prohibition, and the thing is unlaw-
ful, though there be no prohibitory words in the statute.” 
1 J. Kent, Commentaries on American Law 436 (1826). 

We never have classified as a tax an exaction imposed

for violation of the law, and so too, we never have classi-
fied as a tax an exaction described in the legislation itself 
as a penalty.  To be sure, we have sometimes treated as a 
tax a statutory exaction (imposed for something other 
than a violation of law) which bore an agnostic label that 
does not entail the significant constitutional consequences 

background image 21 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

of a penalty—such as “license” (License Tax Cases, 5 Wall. 
462 (1867)) or “surcharge” (New York v. United States
supra.).  But we have never—never—treated as a tax an 
exaction which faces up to the critical difference between
a tax and a penalty, and explicitly denominates the exac-
tion a “penalty.”  Eighteen times in §5000A itself and else- 
where throughout the Act, Congress called the exaction in
§5000A(b) a “penalty.”

That §5000A imposes not a simple tax but a mandate to

which a penalty is attached is demonstrated by the fact
that some are exempt from the tax who are not ex-
empt from the mandate—a distinction that would make
no sense if the mandate were not a mandate.  Section 
5000A(d) exempts three classes of people from the defini-
tion of “applicable individual” subject to the minimum
coverage requirement: Those with religious objections or
who participate in a “health care sharing ministry,”
§5000A(d)(2); those who are “not lawfully present” in the 
United States, §5000A(d)(3); and those who are incarcer-
ated, §5000A(d)(4).  Section 5000A(e) then creates a sepa-
rate set of exemptions, excusing from liability for the
penalty certain individuals who are subject to the mini-
mum coverage requirement: Those who cannot afford
coverage, §5000A(e)(1); who earn too little income to re-
quire filing a tax return, §5000A(e)(2); who are members
of an Indian tribe, §5000A(e)(3); who experience only short
gaps in coverage, §5000A(e)(4); and who, in the judgment
of the Secretary of Health and Human Services, “have
suffered a hardship with respect to the capability to obtain
coverage,” §5000A(e)(5).  If §5000A were a tax, these two
classes of exemption would make no sense; there being no 
requirement, all the exemptions would attach to the pen-
alty (renamed tax) alone.

In the face of all these indications of a regulatory re-

quirement accompanied by a penalty, the Solicitor General
assures us that “neither the Treasury Department nor the 

background image 22 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

Department of Health and Human Services interprets 
Section 5000A as imposing a legal obligation,” Petitioners’ 
Minimum Coverage Brief 61, and that “[i]f [those subject 
to the Act] pay the tax penalty, they’re in compliance with
the law,” Tr. of Oral Arg. 50 (Mar. 26, 2012).  These self-
serving litigating positions are entitled to no weight. 
What counts is what the statute says, and that is entirely 
clear.  It is worth noting, moreover, that these assurances 
contradict the Government’s position in related litigation. 
Shortly before the Affordable Care Act was passed, the
Commonwealth of Virginia enacted Va. Code Ann. §38.2–
3430.1:1 (Lexis Supp. 2011), which states, “No resident of 
[the] Commonwealth . . . shall be required to obtain or 
maintain a policy of individual insurance coverage except
as required by a court or the Department of Social Ser-
vices . . . .”  In opposing Virginia’s assertion of standing to 
challenge §5000A based on this statute, the Government 
said that “if the minimum coverage provision is unconsti-
tutional, the [Virginia] statute is unnecessary, and if the 
minimum coverage provision is upheld, the state statute is
void under the Supremacy Clause.”  Brief for Appellant
in No. 11–1057 etc. (CA4), p. 29.  But it would be void 
under the Supremacy Clause only if it was contradicted by
a federal “require[ment] to obtain or maintain a policy of
individual insurance coverage.”

Against the mountain of evidence that the minimum 

coverage requirement is what the statute calls it—a re-
quirement—and that the penalty for its violation is what 
the statute calls it—a penalty—the Government brings 
forward the flimsiest of indications to the contrary.  It 
notes that “[t]he minimum coverage provision amends the
Internal Revenue Code to provide that a non-exempted 
individual . . . will owe a monetary penalty, in addition to
the income tax itself,” and that “[t]he [Internal Revenue
Service (IRS)] will assess and collect the penalty in the 
same manner as assessable penalties under the Internal 

background image 23 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

Revenue Code.”  Petitioners’ Minimum Coverage Brief 53. 
The manner of collection could perhaps suggest a tax if 
IRS penalty-collection were unheard-of or rare.  It is not. 
See, e.g., 26 U. S. C. §527(j) (2006 ed.) (IRS-collectible pen- 
alty for failure to make campaign-finance disclosures);
§5761© (IRS-collectible penalty for domestic sales of to- 
bacco products labeled for export); §9707 (IRS-collectible 
penalty for failure to make required health-insurance
premium payments on behalf of mining employees).  In 
Reorganized CF&I Fabricators of Utah, Inc., 518 U. S. 
213, we held that an exaction not only enforced by the 
Commissioner of Internal Revenue but even called a “tax” 
was in fact a penalty.  “[I]f the concept of penalty means
anything,” we said, “it means punishment for an unlawful
act or omission.”  Id.,  at 224.  See also Lipke v. Lederer
259 U. S. 557 (1922) (same).  Moreover, while the penalty 
is assessed and collected by the IRS, §5000A is adminis-
tered both by that agency and by the Department of 
Health and Human Services (and also the Secretary of 
Veteran Affairs), see §5000A(e)(1)(D), (e)(5), (f)(1)(A)(v),
(f)(1)(E) (2006 ed., Supp. IV), which is responsible for 
defining its substantive scope—a feature that would be
quite extraordinary for taxes. 

The Government points out that “[t]he amount of the

penalty will be calculated as a percentage of household 
income for federal income tax purposes, subject to a floor 
and [a] ca[p],” and that individuals who earn so little 
money that they “are not required to file income tax re-
turns for the taxable year are not subject to the penalty”
(though they are, as we discussed earlier, subject to the
mandate).  Petitioners’ Minimum Coverage Brief 12, 53.
But varying a penalty according to ability to pay is an 
utterly familiar practice.  See, e.g.,  33  U. S. C.  §1319(d) 
(2006 ed., Supp. IV) (“In determining the amount of a civil 
penalty the court shall consider . . . the economic impact of
the penalty on the violator”); see also 6 U. S. C. §488e©; 7 

background image 24 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

U. S. C. §§7734(b)(2), 8313(b)(2); 12 U. S. C. §§1701q–1(d)(3), 
1723i©(3), 1735f–14©(3), 1735f–15(d)(3), 4585©(2); 15
U. S. C. §§45(m)(1)(C), 77h–1(g)(3), 78u–2(d), 80a–9(d)(4),
80b–3(i)(4), 1681s(a)(2)(B), 1717a(b)(3), 1825(b)(1), 2615(a)
(2)(B), 5408(b)(2); 33 U. S. C. §2716a(a).

The last of the feeble arguments in favor of petition- 

ers that we will address is the contention that what this 
statute repeatedly calls a penalty is in fact a tax because it
contains no scienter requirement.  The presence of such a 
requirement suggests a penalty—though one can imagine 
a tax imposed only on willful action; but the absence of 
such a requirement does not suggest a tax.  Penalties for 
absolute-liability offenses are commonplace.  And where a 
statute is silent as to scienter, we traditionally presume 
a  mens rea requirement if the statute imposes a “severe
penalty.”  Staples v. United States, 511 U. S. 600, 618 
(1994).  Since we have an entire jurisprudence addressing 
when it is that a scienter requirement should be inferred 
from a penalty, it is quite illogical to suggest that a
penalty is not a penalty for want of an express scienter 
requirement.

And the nail in the coffin is that the mandate and pen-

alty are located in Title I of the Act, its operative core, 
rather than where a tax would be found—in Title IX, 
containing the Act’s “Revenue Provisions.”  In sum, “the 
terms of [the] act rende[r] it unavoidable,” Parsons v. 
Bedford, 3 Pet. 433, 448 (1830), that Congress imposed a 
regulatory penalty, not a tax.

For all these reasons, to say that the Individual Man-

date merely imposes a tax is not to interpret the statute 
but to rewrite it.  Judicial tax-writing is particularly troubl- 
ing.  Taxes have never been popular, see, e.g., Stamp Act
of 1765, and in part for that reason, the Constitution
requires tax increases to originate in the House of Repre-
sentatives.  See Art. I, §7, cl. 1.  That is to say, they must
originate in the legislative body most accountable to the 

background image 25 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

people, where legislators must weigh the need for the tax 
against the terrible price they might pay at their next
election, which is never more than two years off.  The 
Federalist No. 58 “defend[ed] the decision to give the
origination power to the House on the ground that the
Chamber that is more accountable to the people should 
have the primary role in raising revenue.”  United States 
v.  Munoz-Flores, 495 U. S. 385, 395 (1990).  We have no 
doubt that Congress knew precisely what it was doing 
when it rejected an earlier version of this legislation that
imposed a tax instead of a requirement-with-penalty.  See 
Affordable Health Care for America Act, H. R. 3962, 111th 
Cong., 1st Sess., §501 (2009); America’s Healthy Future
Act of 2009, S. 1796, 111th Cong., 1st Sess., §1301.  Impos-
ing a tax through judicial legislation inverts the constitu-
tional scheme, and places the power to tax in the branch of
government least accountable to the citizenry. 

Finally, we must observe that rewriting §5000A as a tax 

in order to sustain its constitutionality would force us to 
confront a difficult constitutional question: whether this is 
a direct tax that must be apportioned among the States
according to their population.  Art. I, §9, cl. 4.  Perhaps it
is not (we have no need to address the point); but the 
meaning of the Direct Tax Clause is famously unclear, and 
its application here is a question of first impression that
deserves more thoughtful consideration than the lick-and-
a-promise accorded by the Government and its supporters. 
The Government’s opening brief did not even address the 
question—perhaps because, until today, no federal court 
has accepted the implausible argument that §5000A is
an exercise of the tax power.  And once respondents raised
the issue, the Government devoted a mere 21 lines of its 
reply brief to the issue.  Petitioners’ Minimum Coverage 
Reply Brief 25.  At oral argument, the most prolonged
statement about the issue was just over 50 words.  Tr. of 
Oral Arg. 79 (Mar. 27, 2012).  One would expect this Court 

background image 26 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

to demand more than fly-by-night briefing and argument 
before deciding a difficult constitutional question of first 
impression. 

III 

The Anti-Injunction Act 

There is another point related to the Individual Man-

date that we must discuss—a point that logically should 
have been discussed first: Whether jurisdiction over the 
challenges to the minimum-coverage provision is precluded 
by the Anti-Injunction Act, which provides that “no suit
for the purpose of restraining the assessment or collection 
of any tax shall be maintained in any court by any per-
son,” 26 U. S. C. §7421(a) (2006 ed.).

We have left the question to this point because it 

seemed to us that the dispositive question whether the 
minimum-coverage provision is a tax is more appropriately 
addressed in the significant constitutional context of 
whether it is an exercise of Congress’ taxing power.  Hav-
ing found that it is not, we have no difficulty in deciding 
that these suits do not have “the purpose of restraining 
the assessment or collection of any tax.”6 
—————— 

6

The  amicus  appointed to defend the proposition that the Anti-

Injunction Act deprives us of jurisdiction stresses that the penalty for

failing to comply with the mandate “shall be assessed and collected

in the same manner as an assessable penalty under subchapter B of
chapter 68,” 26 U. S. C. §5000A(g)(1) (2006 ed., Supp. IV), and that 

such penalties “shall be assessed and collected in the same manner

as taxes,” §6671(a) (2006 ed.).  But that point seems to us to confirm 

the  inapplicability of the Anti-Injunction Act.  That the penalty is to 
be “assessed and collected in the same manner as taxes” refutes the 

proposition that it is  a  tax for all statutory purposes, including with 
respect to the Anti-Injunction Act.  Moreover, elsewhere in the Internal 

Revenue Code, Congress has provided both that a particular payment 

shall be “assessed and collected” in the same manner as a tax and that 
no suit shall be maintained to restrain the assessment or collection of 

the payment.  See, e.g.,  §§7421(b)(1), §6901(a); §6305(a), (b).  The 

background image 27 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

The Government and those who support its position on

this point make the remarkable argument that §5000A is
not a tax for purposes of the Anti-Injunction Act, see Brief 
for Petitioners in No. 11–398 (Anti-Injunction Act), but
is a tax for constitutional purposes, see Petitioners’ Mini-
mum Coverage Brief 52–62.  The rhetorical device that 
tries to cloak this argument in superficial plausibility is 
the same device employed in arguing that for constitu-
tional purposes the minimum-coverage provision is a tax:
confusing the question of what Congress did  with the 
question of what Congress could have done.  What quali-
fies as a tax for purposes of the Anti-Injunction Act, unlike
what qualifies as a tax for purposes of the Constitution, is
entirely within the control of Congress.  Compare Bailey v. 
George, 259 U. S. 16, 20 (1922) (Anti-Injunction Act barred 
suit to restrain collections under the Child Labor Tax 
Law), with Child Labor Tax Case, 259 U. S., at 36–41 
(holding the same law unconstitutional as exceeding Con-
gress’ taxing power).  Congress could have defined “tax”
for purposes of that statute in such fashion as to exclude 
some exactions that in fact are “taxes.”  It might have
prescribed, for example, that a particular exercise of the 
taxing power “shall not be regarded as a tax for purposes 
of the Anti-Injunction Act.”  But there is no such prescrip-
tion here.  What the Government would have us believe in 

—————— 
latter directive would be superfluous if the former invoked the Anti-
Injunction Act.

 Amicus also suggests that the penalty should be treated as a tax

because it is an assessable penalty, and the Code’s assessment provi-
sion authorizes the Secretary of the Treasury to assess “all taxes (in-

cluding interest, additional amounts, additions to the tax, and as-

sessable penalties) imposed by this title.”  §6201(a) (2006 ed., Supp. 
IV).  But the fact that such items are included as “taxes” for purposes of

assessment does not establish that they are included as “taxes” for 

purposes of other sections of the Code, such as the Anti-Injunction Act,
that do not contain similar “including” language. 

background image 28 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

these cases is that the very same textual indications that
show this is not a tax under the Anti-Injunction Act show 
that it is a tax under the Constitution.  That carries ver-
bal wizardry too far, deep into the forbidden land of the
sophists. 

IV 

The Medicaid Expansion 

We now consider respondents’ second challenge to the 

constitutionality of the ACA, namely, that the Act’s dra-
matic expansion of the Medicaid program exceeds Con-
gress’ power to attach conditions to federal grants to the 
States. 

The ACA does not legally compel the States to partici-

pate in the expanded Medicaid program, but the Act au-
thorizes a severe sanction for any State that refuses to go 
along: termination of all the State’s Medicaid funding.  For 
the average State, the annual federal Medicaid subsidy is
equal to more than one-fifth of the State’s expenditures.7 
A State forced out of the program would not only lose this 
huge sum but would almost certainly find it necessary to 
increase its own health-care expenditures substantially, 
requiring either a drastic reduction in funding for other
programs or a large increase in state taxes.  And these 
new taxes would come on top of the federal taxes already
paid by the State’s citizens to fund the Medicaid program
in other States. 

The States challenging the constitutionality of the ACA’s

Medicaid Expansion contend that, for these practical
reasons, the Act really does not give them any choice at
all.  As proof of this, they point to the goal and the struc-

—————— 

7

“State expenditures” is used here to mean annual expenditures from 

the States’ own funding sources, and it excludes federal grants unless 
otherwise noted. 

background image 29 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

ture of the ACA.  The goal of the Act is to provide near-
universal medical coverage, 42 U. S. C. §18091(2)(D), and 
without 100% State participation in the Medicaid pro-
gram, attainment of this goal would be thwarted.  Even if 
States could elect to remain in the old Medicaid program, 
while declining to participate in the Expansion, there
would be a gaping hole in coverage.  And if a substantial 
number of States were entirely expelled from the program, 
the number of persons without coverage would be even
higher. 

In light of the ACA’s goal of near-universal coverage,

petitioners argue, if Congress had thought that anything 
less than 100% state participation was a realistic possibil-
ity, Congress would have provided a backup scheme.  But 
no such scheme is to be found anywhere in the more than
900 pages of the Act.  This shows, they maintain, that
Congress was certain that the ACA’s Medicaid offer was 
one that no State could refuse. 

In response to this argument, the Government contends

that any congressional assumption about uniform state
participation was based on the simple fact that the offer 
of federal funds associated with the expanded coverage is 
such a generous gift that no State would want to turn it
down. 

To evaluate these arguments, we consider the extent of

the Federal Government’s power to spend money and to 
attach conditions to money granted to the States. 

No one has ever doubted that the Constitution author-

izes the Federal Government to spend money, but for
many years the scope of this power was unsettled.  The 
Constitution grants Congress the power to collect taxes “to
. . . provide for the . . . general Welfare of the United 
States,” Art. I, §8, cl. 1, and from “the foundation of the
Nation sharp differences of opinion have persisted as to 

background image 30 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

the true interpretation of the phrase” “the general wel-
fare.”  Butler, 297 U. S., at 65.  Madison, it has been said, 
thought that the phrase “amounted to no more than a
reference to the other powers enumerated in the subse-
quent clauses of the same section,” while Hamilton “main-
tained the clause confers a power separate and distinct
from those later enumerated [and] is not restricted in
meaning by the grant of them.”  Ibid

The Court resolved this dispute in Butler.  Writing for

the Court, Justice Roberts opined that the Madisonian
view would make Article I’s grant of the spending power a 
“mere tautology.”  Ibid.  To avoid that, he adopted Hamil-
ton’s approach and found that “the power of Congress to 
authorize expenditure of public moneys for public pur-
poses is not limited by the direct grants of legislative
power found in the Constitution.”  Id., at 66.  Instead, he 
wrote, the spending power’s “confines are set in the clause 
which confers it, and not in those of section 8 which be-
stow and define the legislative powers of the Congress.” 
Ibid.; see also Steward Machine Co. v. Davis, 301 U. S. 
548, 586–587 (1937); Helvering  v. Davis, 301 U. S. 619, 
640 (1937).

The power to make any expenditure that furthers “the

general welfare” is obviously very broad, and shortly after 
Butler was decided the Court gave Congress wide leeway
to decide whether an expenditure qualifies.  See Helvering
301 U. S., at 640–641.  “The discretion belongs to Con-
gress,” the Court wrote, “unless the choice is clearly 
wrong, a display of arbitrary power, not an exercise of 
judgment.”  Id., at 640.  Since that time, the Court has 
never held that a federal expenditure was not for “the
general welfare.” 

One way in which Congress may spend to promote the 

general welfare is by making grants to the States.  Mone-

background image 31 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

tary grants, so-called grants-in-aid, became more frequent
during the 1930’s, G. Stephens & N. Wikstrom, Ameri- 
can Intergovernmental Relations—A Fragmented Federal
Polity 83 (2007), and by 1950 they had reached $20 billion8 
or 11.6% of state and local government expenditures from 
their own sources.9  By 1970 this number had grown to 
$123.7 billion10 or 29.1% of state and local government 
expenditures from their own sources.11  As of 2010, fed-
eral outlays to state and local governments came to over 
$608 billion or 37.5% of state and local government 
expenditures.12 

When Congress makes grants to the States, it customar-

ily attaches conditions, and this Court has long held that
the Constitution generally permits Congress to do this. 
See  Pennhurst State School and Hospital v. Halderman
451 U. S. 1, 17 (1981); South Dakota v. Dole, 483 U. S. 
203, 206 (1987); Fullilove v. Klutznick, 448 U. S. 448, 474 
(1980) (opinion of Burger, C. J.); Steward Machine, supra, 
at 593. 

This practice of attaching conditions to federal funds 

—————— 

8

This number is expressed in billions of Fiscal Year 2005 dollars. 

9

See Office of Management and Budget, Historical Tables, Budget of

the U. S. Government, Fiscal Year 2013, Table 12.1—Summary Com-

parison of Total Outlays for Grants to State and Local Governments: 
1940–2017 (hereinafter Table 12.1), http://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/

budget/Historicals;  id., Table 15.2—Total Government Expenditures: 

1948–2011 (hereinafter Table 15.2). 

10

This number is expressed in billions of Fiscal Year 2005 dollars. 

11

See Table 12.1; Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of Census, Statistical

Abstract of the United States: 2001, p. 262 (Table 419, Federal Grants-
in-Aid Summary: 1970 to 2001). 

12

See Statistical Abstract of the United States: 2012, p. 268 (Table

431, Federal Grants-in-Aid to State and Local Governments: 1990 to 
2011). 

background image 32 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

greatly increases federal power.  “[O]bjectives not thought
to be within Article I’s enumerated legislative fields, may
nevertheless be attained through the use of the spending 
power and the conditional grant of federal funds.”  Dole
supra, at 207 (internal quotation marks and citation omit-
ted); see also College Savings Bank v.  Florida Prepaid 
Postsecondary Ed. Expense Bd.
, 527 U. S. 666, 686 (1999) 
(by attaching conditions to federal funds, Congress may 
induce the States to “tak[e] certain actions that Congress 
could not require them to take”). 

This formidable power, if not checked in any way, would 

present a grave threat to the system of federalism created
by our Constitution.  If Congress’ “Spending Clause power
to pursue objectives outside of Article I’s enumerated 
legislative fields,” Davis v. Monroe County Bd. of Ed., 526 
U. S. 629, 654 (1999) (KENNEDY, J., dissenting) (internal
quotation marks omitted), is “limited only by Congress’ 
notion of the general welfare, the reality, given the vast 
financial resources of the Federal Government, is that 
the Spending Clause gives ‘power to the Congress to tear 
down the barriers, to invade the states’ jurisdiction, and to 
become a parliament of the whole people, subject to no 
restrictions save such as are self-imposed,’” Dolesupra, at 
217 (O’Connor, J., dissenting) (quoting Butler, 297 U. S., 
at 78).  “[T]he Spending Clause power, if wielded without
concern for the federal balance, has the potential to oblite-
rate distinctions between national and local spheres of
interest and power by permitting the Federal Government 
to set policy in the most sensitive areas of traditional
state concern, areas which otherwise would lie outside 
its reach.”  Davis, supra, at 654–655 (KENNEDY,  J., 
dissenting).

Recognizing this potential for abuse, our cases have long 

held that the power to attach conditions to grants to the 
States has limits.  See, e.g.,  Dole,  supra, at 207–208; id., 
at 207 (spending power is “subject to several general re- 

background image 33 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

strictions articulated in our cases”).  For one thing, any
such conditions must be unambiguous so that a State at 
least knows what it is getting into.  See Pennhurst, supra, 
at 17.  Conditions must also be related “to the federal 
interest in particular national projects or programs,” 
Massachusetts v. United States, 435 U. S. 444, 461 (1978),
and the conditional grant of federal funds may not “induce
the States to engage in activities that would themselves be 
unconstitutional,” Dole, supra, at 210; see Lawrence County 
v. Lead-Deadwood School Dist. No. 40–1, 469 U. S. 
256, 269–270 (1985).  Finally, while Congress may seek to
induce States to accept conditional grants, Congress may 
not cross the “point at which pressure turns into compul-
sion, and ceases to be inducement.”  Steward Machine, 301 
U. S., at 590.  Accord, College Savings Bank, supra, at 687; 
Metropolitan Washington Airports Authority v. Citizens for 
Abatement of Aircraft Noise, Inc.
, 501 U. S. 252, 285 (1991) 
(White, J., dissenting); Dolesupra, at 211. 

When federal legislation gives the States a real choice 

whether to accept or decline a federal aid package, the
federal-state relationship is in the nature of a contractual
relationship.  See Barnes  v. Gorman, 536 U. S. 181, 186 
(2002); Pennhurst, 451 U. S., at 17.  And just as a contract
is voidable if coerced, “[t]he legitimacy of Congress’ power 
to legislate under the spending power . . . rests on whether 
the State voluntarily and knowingly accepts the terms 
of the ‘contract.’ ”  Ibid.  (emphasis added).  If a federal 
spending program coerces participation the States have 
not “exercise[d] their choice”—let alone made an “informed 
choice.”  Id., at 17, 25. 

Coercing States to accept conditions risks the destruc-

tion of the “unique role of the States in our system.” 
Davis,  supra, at 685 (KENNEDY, J., dissenting).  “[T]he
Constitution has never been understood to confer upon 
Congress the ability to require the States to govern accord-
ing to Congress’ instructions.”  New York, 505 U. S., at 

background image 34 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

162.  Congress may not “simply commandeer the legisla-
tive processes of the States by directly compelling them to
enact and enforce a federal regulatory program.”  Id.
at 161 (internal quotation marks and brackets omitted).
Congress effectively engages in this impermissible com-
pulsion when state participation in a federal spending
program is coerced, so that the States’ choice whether to
enact or administer a federal regulatory program is ren-
dered illusory.

Where all Congress has done is to “encourag[e] state

regulation rather than compe[l] it, state governments 
remain responsive to the local electorate’s preferences; 
state officials remain accountable to the people.  [But] 
where the Federal Government compels States to regulate,
the accountability of both state and federal officials is 
diminished.”  New York, supra, at 168. 

Amici who support the Government argue that forcing

state employees to implement a federal program is more 
respectful of federalism than using federal workers to
implement that program.  See, e.g., Brief for Service Em-
ployees International Union et al. as Amici Curiae in No. 
11–398, pp. 25–26.  They note that Congress, instead of 
expanding Medicaid, could have established an entirely 
federal program to provide coverage for the same group of 
people.  By choosing to structure Medicaid as a cooperative
federal-state program, they contend, Congress allows for
more state control.  Ibid

This argument reflects a view of federalism that our

cases have rejected—and with good reason.  When Con-
gress compels the States to do its bidding, it blurs the 
lines of political accountability.  If the Federal Govern-
ment makes a controversial decision while acting on its
own, “it is the Federal Government that makes the deci-
sion in full view of the public, and it will be federal offi-
cials that suffer the consequences if the decision turns out
to be detrimental or unpopular.”  New York, 505 U. S., at 

background image 35 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

168.  But when the Federal Government compels the
States to take unpopular actions, “it may be state officials 
who will bear the brunt of public disapproval, while the
federal officials who devised the regulatory program may
remain insulated from the electoral ramifications of their 
decision.”  Id., at 169; see Printz, supra, at 930.  For this 
reason, federal officeholders may view this “departur[e]
from the federal structure to be in their personal interests
. . . as a means of shifting responsibility for the eventual
decision.”  New York, 505 U. S., at 182–183.  And even state 
officials may favor such a “departure from the constitu-
tional plan,” since uncertainty concerning responsibility 
may also permit them to escape accountability.  Id., at 
182.  If a program is popular, state officials may claim 
credit; if it is unpopular, they may protest that they were
merely responding to a federal directive.

Once it is recognized that spending-power legislation 

cannot coerce state participation, two questions remain:
(1) What is the meaning of coercion in this context?  (2) Is
the ACA’s expanded Medicaid coverage coercive?  We now 
turn to those questions. 

The answer to the first of these questions—the meaning

of coercion in the present context—is straightforward.  As 
we have explained, the legitimacy of attaching conditions 
to federal grants to the States depends on the voluntari-
ness of the States’ choice to accept or decline the offered
package.  Therefore, if States really have no choice other 
than to accept the package, the offer is coercive, and the
conditions cannot be sustained under the spending power.
And as our decision in South Dakota v. Dole makes clear, 
theoretical voluntariness is not enough. 

In South Dakota v. Dole, we considered whether the 

spending power permitted Congress to condition 5% of the 

background image 36 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

State’s federal highway funds on the State’s adoption of
a minimum drinking age of 21 years.  South Dakota ar-
gued that the program was impermissibly coercive, but we 
disagreed, reasoning that “Congress ha[d] directed only
that a State desiring to establish a minimum drinking age
lower than 21 lose a relatively small percentage of certain
federal highway funds.”  483 U. S., at 211. Because “all 
South Dakota would lose if she adhere[d] to her chosen 
course as to a suitable minimum drinking age [was] 5%
of the funds otherwise obtainable under specified high-
way grant programs,” we found that “Congress ha[d] of- 
fered relatively mild encouragement to the States to enact
higher minimum drinking ages than they would otherwise
choose.”  Ibid.  Thus, the decision whether to comply with
the federal condition “remain[ed] the prerogative of the
States  not merely in theory but in fact,” and so the pro-
gram at issue did not exceed Congress’ power.  Id., at 211– 
212 (emphasis added).

The question whether a law enacted under the spending

power is coercive in fact will sometimes be difficult, but 
where Congress has plainly “crossed the line distinguish-
ing encouragement from coercion,” New York, supra, at 
175, a federal program that coopts the States’ political 
processes must be declared unconstitutional.  “[T]he fed-
eral balance is too essential a part of our constitutional 
structure and plays too vital a role in securing freedom for
us to admit inability to intervene.”  Lopez, 514 U. S., at 
578 (KENNEDY, J., concurring). 

The Federal Government’s argument in this case at best 

pays lip service to the anticoercion principle.  The Federal 
Government suggests that it is sufficient if States are 
“free,  as a matter of law, to turn down” federal funds. 
Brief for Respondents in No. 11–400, p. 17 (emphasis 
added); see also id., at 25.  According to the Federal Gov-

background image 37 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

ernment, neither the amount of the offered federal funds 
nor the amount of the federal taxes extracted from the 
taxpayers of a State to pay for the program in question is 
relevant in determining whether there is impermissible 
coercion.  Id., at 41–46. 

This argument ignores reality.  When a heavy federal

tax is levied to support a federal program that offers large 
grants to the States, States may, as a practical matter, be 
unable to refuse to participate in the federal program and 
to substitute a state alternative.  Even if a State believes 
that the federal program is ineffective and inefficient, 
withdrawal would likely force the State to impose a huge 
tax increase on its residents, and this new state tax would 
come on top of the federal taxes already paid by residents 
to support subsidies to participating States.13 

Acceptance of the Federal Government’s interpreta-

tion of the anticoercion rule would permit Congress to dic-
tate policy in areas traditionally governed primarily at the 
state or local level.  Suppose, for example, that Congress 
enacted legislation offering each State a grant equal to the
State’s entire annual expenditures for primary and sec-
ondary education.  Suppose also that this funding came 
with conditions governing such things as school curricu-
lum, the hiring and tenure of teachers, the drawing of 
school districts, the length and hours of the school day, the 

—————— 

13 

JUSTICE  GINSBURG argues that “[a] State . . . has no claim on the 

money its residents pay in federal taxes.”  Ante, at 59, n. 26.  This is 

true as a formal matter.  “When the United States Government taxes 

United States citizens, it taxes them ‘in their individual capacities’ as
‘the people of America’—not as residents of a particular State.”  Ante, at 

58, n. 26 (quoting U. S. Term Limits, Inc. v. Thornton, 514 U. S. 779, 
839 (1995) (KENNEDY, J., concurring)).  But unless JUSTICE  GINSBURG 

thinks that there is no limit to the amount of money that can be

squeezed out of taxpayers, heavy federal taxation diminishes the 
practical ability of States to collect their own taxes. 

background image 38 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

school calendar, a dress code for students, and rules for 
student discipline.  As a matter of law, a State could turn 
down that offer, but if it did so, its residents would not 
only be required to pay the federal taxes needed to support
this expensive new program, but they would also be forced 
to pay an equivalent amount in state taxes.  And if the 
State gave in to the federal law, the State and its subdivi-
sions would surrender their traditional authority in the 
field of education.  Asked at oral argument whether such
a law would be allowed under the spending power, the 
Solicitor General responded that it would.  Tr. of Oral Arg. 
44–45 (Mar. 28, 2012). 

Whether federal spending legislation crosses the line

from enticement to coercion is often difficult to determine, 
and courts should not conclude that legislation is uncon-
stitutional on this ground unless the coercive nature of an
offer is unmistakably clear.  In this case, however, there 
can be no doubt.  In structuring the ACA, Congress unam-
biguously signaled its belief that every State would have 
no real choice but to go along with the Medicaid Expan-
sion.  If the anticoercion rule does not apply in this case,
then there is no such rule. 

The dimensions of the Medicaid program lend strong

support to the petitioner States’ argument that refusing to
accede to the conditions set out in the ACA is not a realis-
tic option.  Before the ACA’s enactment, Medicaid funded 
medical care for pregnant women, families with depend-
ents, children, the blind, the elderly, and the disabled.  See 
42 U. S. C. §1396a(a)(10) (2006 ed., Supp. IV).  The ACA 
greatly expands the program’s reach, making new funds
available to States that agree to extend coverage to all 
individuals who are under age 65 and have incomes below 

background image 39 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

133% of the federal poverty line.  See  §1396a(a) 
(10)(A)(i)(VIII).  Any State that refuses to expand
its Medicaid programs in this way is threatened with a
severe sanction: the loss of all its federal Medicaid funds. 
See §1396c (2006 ed.).

Medicaid has long been the largest federal program of 

grants to the States.  See Brief for Respondents in No. 11– 
400, at 37.  In 2010, the Federal Government directed 
more than $552 billion in federal funds to the States.  See 
Nat. Assn. of State Budget Officers, 2010 State Expendi-
ture Report: Examining Fiscal 2009–2011 State Spending, 
p. 7 (2011) (NASBO Report).  Of this, more than $233 
billion went to pre-expansion Medicaid.  See id., at 47.14 
This amount equals nearly 22% of all state expenditures 
combined
.  See id., at 7. 

The States devote a larger percentage of their budgets 

to Medicaid than to any other item.  Id.,  at  5.    Federal  
funds account for anywhere from 50% to 83% of each 
State’s total Medicaid expenditures, see §1396d(b) (2006 ed., 
Supp. IV); most States receive more than $1 billion in 
federal Medicaid funding; and a quarter receive more than 

—————— 

14

The Federal Government has a higher number for federal spending 

on Medicaid.  According to the Office of Management and Budget, 
federal grants to the States for Medicaid amounted to nearly $273 
billion in Fiscal Year 2010.  See Office of Management and Bud- 
get, Historical Tables, Budget of the U. S. Government, Fiscal Year 
2013, Table 12.3—Total Outlays for Grants to State and Local Gov-
ernments by Function, Agency, and Program:  1940–2013, http:// 
www.whitehouse.gov/omb/budget/Historicals.  In that Fiscal Year, total 
federal outlays for grants to state and local governments amounted to 
over $608 billion, see Table 12.1, and state and local government 
expenditures from their own sources amounted to $1.6 trillion, see 
Table 15.2.  Using these numbers, 44.8% of all federal outlays to both 
state and local governments was allocated to Medicaid, amounting to 
16.8% of all state and local expenditures from their own sources. 

background image 40 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

$5 billion, NASBO Report 47.  These federal dollars total 
nearly two thirds—64.6%—of all Medicaid expenditures 
nationwide.15  Id., at 46. 

The Court of Appeals concluded that the States failed to 

establish coercion in this case in part because the “states 
have the power to tax and raise revenue, and therefore can 
create and fund programs of their own if they do not like 
Congress’s terms.”  648 F. 3d 1235, 1268 (CA11 2011); see 
Brief for Sen. Harry Reid et al. as Amici Curiae in No. 11– 
400, p. 21 (“States may always choose to decrease expendi-
tures on other programs or to raise revenues”).  But the 
sheer size of this federal spending program in relation to 
state expenditures means that a State would be very hard 
pressed to compensate for the loss of federal funds by 
cutting other spending or raising additional revenue. 
Arizona, for example, commits 12% of its state expendi-
tures to Medicaid, and relies on the Federal Government 
to provide the rest: $5.6 billion, equaling roughly one-third 
of Arizona’s annual state expenditures of $17 billion.  See 
NASBO Report 7, 47.  Therefore, if Arizona lost federal 
Medicaid funding, the State would have to commit an 
additional 33% of all its state expenditures to fund an 
equivalent state program along the lines of pre-expansion 
Medicaid.  This means that the State would have to allo-
cate 45% of its annual expenditures for that one purpose. 
See ibid

The States are far less reliant on federal funding for any 

other program.  After Medicaid, the next biggest federal 

—————— 

15

The Federal Government reports a higher percentage.  According

to Medicaid.gov, in Fiscal Year 2010, the Federal Government made 
Medicaid payments in the amount of nearly $260 billion, repre-

senting 67.79% of total Medicaid payments of $383 billion.  See 

www.medicaid.gov/Medicaid-CHIP-Program-Information /By-State/By-\\ State.html. 

background image 41 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

funding item is aid to support elementary and secondary
education, which amounts to 12.8% of total federal outlays
to the States, see id., at 7, 16, and equals only 6.6% of 
all state expenditures combined.  See ibid.  In Arizona, 
for example, although federal Medicaid expenditures are
equal to 33% of all state expenditures, federal education
funds amount to only 9.8% of all state expenditures.  See 
ibid.  And even in States with less than average federal
Medicaid funding, that funding is at least twice the size of 
federal education funding as a percentage of state expend-
itures.  Id., at 7, 16, 47. 

A State forced out of the Medicaid program would face

burdens in addition to the loss of federal Medicaid fund-
ing.  For example, a nonparticipating State might be found 
to be ineligible for other major federal funding sources, 
such as Temporary Assistance for Needy Families (TANF), 
which is premised on the expectation that States will 
participate in Medicaid.  See 42 U. S. C. §602(a)(3) (2006
ed.) (requiring that certain beneficiaries of TANF funds be
“eligible for medical assistance under the State[’s Medi-
caid] plan”).  And withdrawal or expulsion from the Medi-
caid program would not relieve a State’s hospitals of their 
obligation under federal law to provide care for patients
who are unable to pay for medical services.  The Emer-
gency Medical Treatment and Active Labor Act, §1395dd,
requires hospitals that receive any federal funding to
provide stabilization care for indigent patients but does 
not offer federal funding to assist facilities in carrying out 
its mandate.  Many of these patients are now covered by 
Medicaid.  If providers could not look to the Medicaid
program to pay for this care, they would find it exceed-
ingly difficult to comply with federal law unless they were 
given substantial state support.  See, e.g., Brief for Econ-
omists as Amici Curiae in No 11–400, p. 11. 

For these reasons, the offer that the ACA makes to the 

States—go along with a dramatic expansion of Medicaid or 

background image 42 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

potentially lose all federal Medicaid funding—is quite 
unlike anything that we have seen in a prior spending-
power case.  In South Dakota v. Dole, the total amount 
that the States would have lost if every single State
had refused to comply with the 21-year-old drinking
age was approximately $614.7 million—or about 0.19% 
of all state expenditures combined.  See Nat. Assn. 
of State Budget Officers, 1989 (Fiscal Years 1987– 
1989 Data) State Expenditure Report 10, 84 (1989), 
http:%%//%%www.nasbo.org/publications-data/state-expenditure-\\ report/archives.  South Dakota stood to lose, at most, 
funding that amounted to less than 1% of its annual state 
expenditures.  See ibid.  Under the ACA, by contrast, the 
Federal Government has threatened to withhold 42.3% of 
all federal outlays to the states, or approximately $233
billion.  See NASBO Report 7, 10, 47.  South Dakota 
stands to lose federal funding equaling 28.9% of its annual 
state expenditures.  See id., at 7, 47.  Withholding $614.7
million, equaling only 0.19% of all state expenditures 
combined, is aptly characterized as “relatively mild en-
couragement,” but threatening to withhold $233 billion, 
equaling 21.86% of all state expenditures combined, is a 
different matter. 

What the statistics suggest is confirmed by the goal

and structure of the ACA.  In crafting the ACA, Congress
clearly expressed its informed view that no State could 
possibly refuse the offer that the ACA extends.

The stated goal of the ACA is near-universal health care 

coverage.  To achieve this goal, the ACA mandates that
every person obtain a minimum level of coverage.  It at-
tempts to reach this goal in several different ways.  The 
guaranteed issue and community-rating provisions are 
designed to make qualifying insurance available and 
affordable for persons with medical conditions that may 

background image 43 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

require expensive care.  Other ACA provisions seek to 
make such policies more affordable for people of modest 
means.  Finally, for low-income individuals who are 
simply not able to obtain insurance, Congress expanded 
Medicaid, transforming it from a program covering only
members of a limited list of vulnerable groups into a pro-
gram that provides at least the requisite minimum level 
of coverage for the poor.  See 42 U. S. C. §§1396a(a)
(10)(A)(i)(VIII) (2006 ed., Supp. IV), 1396u–7(a), (b)(5), 
18022(a).  This design was intended to provide at least 
a specified minimum level of coverage for all Americans, 
but the achievement of that goal obviously depends on
participation by every single State.  If any State—not 
to mention all of the 26 States that brought this suit—
chose to decline the federal offer, there would be a gaping
hole in the ACA’s coverage. 

It is true that some persons who are eligible for Medi-

caid coverage under the ACA may be able to secure private 
insurance, either through their employers or by obtain- 
ing subsidized insurance through an exchange.  See 26 
U. S. C. §36B(a) (2006 ed., Supp. IV); Brief for Respond-
ents in No. 11–400, at 12.  But the new federal subsidies 
are not available to those whose income is below the fed-
eral poverty level, and the ACA provides no means, other
than Medicaid, for these individuals to obtain coverage 
and comply with the Mandate.  The Government counters 
that these people will not have to pay the penalty, see, e.g.
Tr. of Oral Arg. 68 (Mar. 28, 2012); Brief for Respondents 
in No. 11–400, at 49–50, but that argument misses the 
point:  Without Medicaid, these individuals will not have 
coverage and the ACA’s goal of near-universal coverage 
will be severely frustrated.

If Congress had thought that States might actually

refuse to go along with the expansion of Medicaid, Con-
gress would surely have devised a backup scheme so that
the most vulnerable groups in our society, those previously 

background image 44 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

eligible for Medicaid, would not be left out in the cold.  But 
nowhere in the over 900-page Act is such a scheme to be 
found.  By contrast, because Congress thought that some
States might decline federal funding for the operation of
a “health benefit exchange,” Congress provided a backup 
scheme; if a State declines to participate in the operation 
of an exchange, the Federal Government will step in
and operate an exchange in that State.  See 42 U. S. C. 
§18041©(1).  Likewise, knowing that States would not 
necessarily provide affordable health insurance for aliens
lawfully present in the United States—because Medicaid
does not require States to provide such coverage—Con- 
gress extended the availability of the new federal insur-
ance subsidies to all aliens.  See 26 U. S. C. §36B© 
(1)(B)(ii) (excepting from the income limit individuals 
who are “not eligible for the medicaid program . . . by
reason of [their] alien status”).  Congress did not make
these subsidies available for citizens with incomes below 
the poverty level because Congress obviously assumed 
that they would be covered by Medicaid.  If Congress had
contemplated that some of these citizens would be left
without Medicaid coverage as a result of a State’s with-
drawal or expulsion from the program, Congress surely 
would have made them eligible for the tax subsidies pro-
vided for low-income aliens. 

These features of the ACA convey an unmistakable

message: Congress never dreamed that any State would 
refuse to go along with the expansion of Medicaid.  Con-
gress well understood that refusal was not a practical
option.

The Federal Government does not dispute the inference

that Congress anticipated 100% state participation, but it
argues that this assumption was based on the fact that 
ACA’s offer was an “exceedingly generous” gift.  Brief for 
Respondents in No. 11–400, at 50.  As the Federal Gov-
ernment sees things, Congress is like the generous bene-

background image 45 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

factor who offers $1 million with few strings attached to 
50 randomly selected individuals.  Just as this benefactor 
might assume that all of these 50 individuals would snap
up his offer, so Congress assumed that every State would 
gratefully accept the federal funds (and conditions) to go
with the expansion of Medicaid. 

This characterization of the ACA’s offer raises obvious 

questions.  If that offer is “exceedingly generous,” as the 
Federal Government maintains, why have more than half 
the States brought this lawsuit, contending that the offer 
is coercive?  And why did Congress find it necessary to 
threaten that any State refusing to accept this “exceed-
ingly generous” gift would risk losing all Medicaid funds? 
Congress could have made just the new funding provided
under the ACA contingent on acceptance of the terms of
the Medicaid Expansion.  Congress took such an approach
in some earlier amendments to Medicaid, separating new 
coverage requirements and funding from the rest of the 
program so that only new funding was conditioned on new 
eligibility extensions.  See, e.g., Social Security Amend-
ments of 1972, 86 Stat. 1465. 

Congress’ decision to do otherwise here reflects its un-

derstanding that the ACA offer is not an “exceedingly 
generous” gift that no State in its right mind would de-
cline.  Instead, acceptance of the offer will impose very
substantial costs on participating States.  It is true that 
the Federal Government will bear most of the initial costs 
associated with the Medicaid Expansion, first paying
100% of the costs of covering newly eligible individuals 
between 2014 and 2016.  42 U. S. C. §1396d(y).  But that 
is just part of the picture.  Participating States will be 
forced to shoulder substantial costs as well, because after 
2019 the Federal Government will cover only 90% of the 
costs associated with the Expansion, see ibid., with state 
spending projected to increase by at least $20 billion by
2020 as a consequence.  Statement of Douglas W. Elmen-

background image 46 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

dorf, CBO’s Analysis of the Major Health Care Legislation 
Enacted in March 2010, p. 24 (Mar. 30, 2011); see also R.
Bovbjerg, B. Ormond, & V. Chen, Kaiser Commission on 
Medicaid and the Uninsured, State Budgets under Federal 
Health Reform: The Extent and Causes of Variations in 
Estimated Impacts 4, n. 27 (Feb. 2011) (estimating new 
state spending at $43.2 billion through 2019).  After 2019, 
state spending is expected to increase at a faster rate; the 
CBO estimates new state spending at $60 billion through 
2021.  Statement of Douglas W. Elmendorf, supra, at 24. 
And these costs may increase in the future because of 
the very real possibility that the Federal Government will 
change funding terms and reduce the percentage of funds 
it will cover.  This would leave the States to bear an in-
creasingly large percentage of the bill.  See Tr. of Oral 
Arg. 74–76 (Mar. 28, 2012).  Finally, after 2015, the States
will have to pick up the tab for 50% of all administrative
costs associated with implementing the new program, see 
§§1396b(a)(2)–(5), (7) (2006 ed., Supp. IV), costs that could 
approach $12 billion between fiscal years 2014 and 2020, 
see Dept. of Health and Human Services, Center for Medi-
caid and Medicare Services, 2010 Actuarial Report on the 
Financial Outlook for Medicaid 30. 

In sum, it is perfectly clear from the goal and structure

of the ACA that the offer of the Medicaid Expansion was
one that Congress understood no State could refuse. The
Medicaid Expansion therefore exceeds Congress’ spending 
power and cannot be implemented. 

Seven Members of the Court agree that the Medicaid 

Expansion, as enacted by Congress, is unconstitutional. 
See Part IV–A to IV–E, supra; Part IV–A, ante, at 45–55 
(opinion of ROBERTS, C. J., joined by BREYER and KAGAN, 

JJ.).  Because the Medicaid Expansion is unconstitutional, 
the question of remedy arises.  The most natural remedy 

background image 47 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

would be to invalidate the Medicaid Expansion.  However, 
the Government proposes—in two cursory sentences at
the very end of its brief—preserving the Expansion.  Under 
its proposal, States would receive the additional Medi-
caid funds if they expand eligibility, but States would 
keep their pre-existing Medicaid funds if they do not
expand eligibility.  We cannot accept the Government’s
suggestion.

The reality that States were given no real choice but to

expand Medicaid was not an accident.  Congress assumed 
States would have no choice, and the ACA depends on
States’ having no choice, because its Mandate requires
low-income individuals to obtain insurance many of them 
can afford only through the Medicaid Expansion.  Fur-
thermore, a State’s withdrawal might subject everyone in
the State to much higher insurance premiums.  That is 
because the Medicaid Expansion will no longer offset the
cost to the insurance industry imposed by the ACA’s in-
surance regulations and taxes, a point that is explained in 
more detail in the severability section below.  To make the 
Medicaid Expansion optional despite the ACA’s structure
and design “ ‘would be to make a new law, not to enforce 
an old one.  This is no part of our duty.’ ”  Trade-Mark 
Cases
, 100 U. S. 82, 99 (1879).

Worse, the Government’s proposed remedy introduces a

new dynamic: States must choose between expanding 
Medicaid or paying huge tax sums to the federal fisc for 
the sole benefit of expanding Medicaid in other States.  If 
this divisive dynamic between and among States can be
introduced at all, it should be by conscious congressional 
choice, not by Court-invented interpretation.  We do not 
doubt that States are capable of making decisions when
put in a tight spot.  We do doubt the authority of this
Court to put them there. 

The Government cites a severability clause codified with

Medicaid in Chapter 7 of the United States Code stating 

background image 48 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

that if “any provision of this chapter, or the application 
thereof to any person or circumstance, is held invalid, the 
remainder of the chapter, and the application of such
provision to other persons or circumstances shall not be
affected thereby.”  42 U. S. C. §1303 (2006 ed.).  But that 
clause tells us only that other provisions in Chapter 7
should not be invalidated if §1396c, the authorization for 
the cut-off of all Medicaid funds, is unconstitutional.  It 
does not tell us that §1396c can be judicially revised, to 
say what it does not say.  Such a judicial power would 
not be called the doctrine of severability but perhaps
the doctrine of amendatory invalidation—similar to the 
amendatory veto that permits the Governors of some 
States to reduce the amounts appropriated in legislation. 
The proof that such a power does not exist is the fact that
it would not preserve other congressional dispositions, but 
would leave it up to the Court what the “validated” legis-
lation will contain.  The Court today opts for permitting 
the cut-off of only incremental Medicaid funding, but it
might just as well have permitted, say, the cut-off of funds 
that represent no more than x percent of the State’s bud-
get.  The Court severs nothing, but simply revises §1396c to
read as the Court would desire. 

We should not accept the Government’s invitation to

attempt to solve a constitutional problem by rewriting the
Medicaid Expansion so as to allow States that reject it 
to retain their pre-existing Medicaid funds.  Worse, the 
Government’s remedy, now adopted by the Court, takes
the ACA and this Nation in a new direction and charts a 
course for federalism that the Court, not the Congress, has
chosen; but under the Constitution, that power and au-
thority do not rest with this Court. 

Severability 

The Affordable Care Act seeks to achieve “near-

background image 49 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

universal” health insurance coverage.  §18091(2)(D) (2006 
ed., Supp. IV).  The two pillars of the Act are the Individ- 
ual Mandate and the expansion of coverage under Medicaid.
In our view, both these central provisions of the Act—the
Individual Mandate and Medicaid Expansion—are invalid. 
It follows, as some of the parties urge, that all other provi-
sions of the Act must fall as well.  The following section
explains the severability principles that require this con-
clusion.  This analysis also shows how closely interrelated
the Act is, and this is all the more reason why it is judicial
usurpation to impose an entirely new mechanism for
withdrawal of Medicaid funding, see Part IV–F, supra
which is one of many examples of how rewriting the Act 
alters its dynamics. 

When an unconstitutional provision is but a part of a

more comprehensive statute, the question arises as to the 
validity of the remaining provisions.  The Court’s author-
ity to declare a statute partially unconstitutional has been
well established since Marbury v. Madison, 1 Cranch 137 
(1803), when the Court severed an unconstitutional provi-
sion from the Judiciary Act of 1789.  And while the Court 
has sometimes applied “at least a modest presumption in 
favor of . . . severability,” C. Nelson, Statutory Interpreta-
tion 144 (2010), it has not always done so, see, e.g., Minne-
sota
 v. Mille Lacs Band of Chippewa Indians, 526 U. S. 
172, 190–195 (1999). 

An automatic or too cursory severance of statutory 

provisions risks “rewrit[ing] a statute and giv[ing] it an
effect altogether different from that sought by the meas-
ure viewed as a whole.”  Railroad Retirement Bd. v. Alton 
R. Co.
, 295 U. S. 330, 362 (1935).  The Judiciary, if it
orders uncritical severance, then assumes the legislative 
function; for it imposes on the Nation, by the Court’s
decree, its own new statutory regime, consisting of poli-

background image 50 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

cies, risks, and duties that Congress did not enact.  That 
can be a more extreme exercise of the judicial power than
striking the whole statute and allowing Congress to ad-
dress the conditions that pertained when the statute was
considered at the outset. 

The Court has applied a two-part guide as the frame-

work for severability analysis.  The test has been deemed 
“well established.”  Alaska Airlines, Inc. v. Brock, 480 
U. S. 678, 684 (1987).  First, if the Court holds a statutory 
provision unconstitutional, it then determines whether
the now truncated statute will operate in the manner Con- 
gress intended.  If not, the remaining provisions must be 
invalidated.  See id., at 685.  In Alaska Airlines, the Court 
clarified that this first inquiry requires more than ask- 
ing whether “the balance of the legislation is incapable of 
functioning independently.”  Id., at 684.    Even  if  the  re-
maining provisions will operate in some coherent way,
that alone does not save the statute.  The question is 
whether the provisions will work as Congress intended. 
The “relevant inquiry in evaluating severability is whether 
the statute will function in a manner consistent with 
the intent of Congress.”  Id., at 685 (emphasis in original). 
See also Free Enterprise Fund v. Public Company Account-
ing Oversight Bd.
, 561 U. S. ___, ___ (2010) (slip op., at 
28) (the Act “remains fully operative as a law with these 
tenure restrictions excised”) (internal quotation marks 
omitted);  United States v. Booker, 543 U. S. 220, 227 
(2005) (“[T]wo provisions . . . must be invalidated in order
to allow the statute to operate in a manner consistent
with congressional intent”); Mille Lacssupra, at 194 (“[E]m- 
bodying as it did one coherent policy, [the entire order]
is inseverable”). 

Second, even if the remaining provisions can operate as

Congress designed them to operate, the Court must de-
termine if Congress would have enacted them standing 
alone and without the unconstitutional portion.  If Con-

background image 51 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

gress would not, those provisions, too, must be invalidated. 
See  Alaska Airlines,  supra, at 685 (“[T]he unconstitu- 
tional provision must be severed unless the statute cre- 
ated in its absence is legislation that Congress would not 
have enacted”); see also Free Enterprise Fund,  supra, at 
___ (slip op., at 29) (“[N]othing in the statute’s text or 
historical context makes it ‘evident’ that Congress, faced 
with the limitations imposed by the Constitution, would 
have preferred no Board at all to a Board whose members
are removable at will”); Ayotte v. Planned Parenthood of 
Northern New Eng.
, 546 U. S. 320, 330 (2006) (“Would the
legislature have preferred what is left of its statute to no 
statute at all”); Denver Area Ed. Telecommunications 
Consortium, Inc.
 v. FCC, 518 U. S. 727, 767 (1996) (plural-
ity opinion) (“Would Congress still have passed §10(a) had
it known that the remaining provisions were invalid” 
(internal quotation marks and brackets omitted)).

The two inquiries—whether the remaining provisions

will operate as Congress designed them, and whether
Congress would have enacted the remaining provisions
standing alone—often are interrelated.  In the ordinary 
course, if the remaining provisions cannot operate accord-
ing to the congressional design (the first inquiry), it almost 
necessarily follows that Congress would not have enacted
them (the second inquiry).  This close interaction may
explain why the Court has not always been precise in
distinguishing between the two.  There are, however, 
occasions in which the severability standard’s first inquiry 
(statutory functionality) is not a proxy for the second
inquiry (whether the Legislature intended the remaining 
provisions to stand alone). 

The Act was passed to enable affordable, “near-universal”

health insurance coverage.  42 U. S. C. §18091(2)(D). 
The resulting, complex statute consists of mandates and 

background image 52 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

other requirements; comprehensive regulation and penal-
ties; some undoubted taxes; and increases in some gov-
ernmental expenditures, decreases in others.  Under the 
severability test set out above, it must be determined if
those provisions function in a coherent way and as Con-
gress would have intended, even when the major provi-
sions establishing the Individual Mandate and Medicaid 
Expansion are themselves invalid.

Congress did not intend to establish the goal of near-

universal coverage without regard to fiscal consequences.
See, e.g., ACA §1563, 124 Stat. 270 (“[T]his Act will reduce 
the Federal deficit between 2010 and 2019”).  And it did 
not intend to impose the inevitable costs on any one indus-
try or group of individuals.  The whole design of the Act 
is to balance the costs and benefits affecting each set
of regulated parties.  Thus, individuals are required to
obtain health insurance.  See 26 U. S. C. §5000A(a).  Insur- 
ance companies are required to sell them insurance re-
gardless of patients’ pre-existing conditions and to comply
with a host of other regulations.  And the companies must 
pay new taxes.  See §4980I (high-cost insurance plans);
42 U. S. C. §§300gg(a)(1), 300gg–4(b) (community rating);
§§300gg–1, 300gg–3, 300gg–4(a) (guaranteed issue);
§300gg–11 (elimination of coverage limits); §300gg–14(a) 
(dependent children up to age 26); ACA §§9010, 10905,
124 Stat. 865, 1017 (excise tax); Health Care and Educa-
tion Reconciliation Act of 2010 (HCERA) §1401, 124 Stat.
1059 (excise tax).  States are expected to expand Medicaid 
eligibility and to create regulated marketplaces called ex- 
changes where individuals can purchase insurance.  See 
42 U. S. C. §§1396a(a)(10)(A)(i)(VIII) (2006 ed., Supp. IV) 
(Medicaid Expansion), 18031 (exchanges).  Some persons
who cannot afford insurance are provided it through the 
Medicaid Expansion, and others are aided in their pur-
chase of insurance through federal subsidies available on
health-insurance exchanges.  See 26 U. S. C. §36B (2006 

background image 53 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

ed., Supp. IV), 42 U. S. C. §18071 (2006 ed., Supp. IV)
(federal subsidies).  The Federal Government’s increased 
spending is offset by new taxes and cuts in other federal
expenditures, including reductions in Medicare and in
federal payments to hospitals.  See, e.g., §1395ww® (Med-
icare cuts); ACA Title IX, Subtitle A, 124 Stat. 847 (“Rev-
enue Offset Provisions”).  Employers with at least 50
employees must either provide employees with adequate 
health benefits or pay a financial exaction if an employee 
who qualifies for federal subsidies purchases insurance
through an exchange.  See 26 U. S. C. §4980H (2006 ed., 
Supp. IV).

In short, the Act attempts to achieve near-universal 

health insurance coverage by spreading its costs to indi-
viduals, insurers, governments, hospitals, and employers—
while, at the same time, offsetting significant portions
of those costs with new benefits to each group.  For ex-
ample, the Federal Government bears the burden of pay-
ing billions for the new entitlements mandated by the 
Medicaid Expansion and federal subsidies for insurance 
purchases on the exchanges; but it benefits from reduc-
tions in the reimbursements it pays to hospitals.  Hospi-
tals lose those reimbursements; but they benefit from the
decrease in uncompensated care, for under the insurance
regulations it is easier for individuals with pre-existing 
conditions to purchase coverage that increases payments
to hospitals.  Insurance companies bear new costs imposed
by a collection of insurance regulations and taxes, including 
“guaranteed issue” and “community rating” requirements
to give coverage regardless of the insured’s pre-existing
conditions; but the insurers benefit from the new, healthy 
purchasers who are forced by the Individual Mandate 
to buy the insurers’ product and from the new low-
income Medicaid recipients who will enroll in insurance 
companies’ Medicaid-funded managed care programs.  In 
summary, the Individual Mandate and Medicaid Expan-

background image 54 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

sion offset insurance regulations and taxes, which offset
reduced reimbursements to hospitals, which offset in-
creases in federal spending.  So, the Act’s major provisions 
are interdependent.

The Act then refers to these interdependencies as

“shared responsibility.”  See ACA Subtitle F, Title I, 124 
Stat. 242 (“Shared Responsibility”); ACA §1501, ibid. 
(same); ACA §1513, id., at 253 (same); ACA §4980H, ibid. 
(same).  In at least six places, the Act describes the Indi-
vidual Mandate as working “together with the other pro-
visions of this Act.”  42 U. S. C. §18091(2)(C) (2006 ed.,
Supp. IV) (working “together” to “add millions of new 
consumers to the health insurance market”); §18091(2)(E) 
(working “together” to “significantly reduce” the economic 
cost of the poorer health and shorter lifespan of the unin-
sured); §18091(2)(F) (working “together” to “lower health
insurance premiums”); §18091(2)(G) (working “together” to
“improve financial security for families”); §18091(2)(I) 
(working “together” to minimize “adverse selection and 
broaden the health insurance risk pool to include healthy 
individuals”); §18091(2)(J) (working “together” to “signif- 
icantly reduce administrative costs and lower health
insurance premiums”).  The Act calls the Individual Man-
date “an essential part” of federal regulation of health
insurance and warns that “the absence of the requirement
would undercut Federal regulation of the health insurance 
market.”  §18091(2)(H). 

One preliminary point should be noted before applying

severability principles to the Act.  To be sure, an argument 
can be made that those portions of the Act that none of the 
parties has standing to challenge cannot be held nonse-
verable.  The response to this argument is that our cases
do not support it.  See, e.g., Williams v. Standard Oil Co. 
of La.
, 278 U. S. 235, 242–244 (1929) (holding nonsever-

background image 55 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

able statutory provisions that did not burden the parties).
It would be particularly destructive of sound government
to apply such a rule with regard to a multifaceted piece of 
legislation like the ACA.  It would take years, perhaps
decades, for each of its provisions to be adjudicated sepa-
rately—and for some of them (those simply expending
federal funds) no one may have separate standing.  The 
Federal Government, the States, and private parties ought 
to know at once whether the entire legislation fails. 

The opinion now explains in Part V–C–1, infra, why the

Act’s major provisions are not severable from the Mandate
and Medicaid Expansion.  It proceeds from the insurance 
regulations and taxes (C–1–a), to the reductions in reim-
bursements to hospitals and other Medicare reductions
(C–1–b), the exchanges and their federal subsidies (C–1–c),
and the employer responsibility assessment (C–1–d). 
Part V–C–2, infra, explains why the Act’s minor provi-
sions also are not severable. 

The Act’s Major Provisions 

Major provisions of the Affordable Care Act—i.e., the 

insurance regulations and taxes, the reductions in federal 
reimbursements to hospitals and other Medicare spend- 
ing reductions, the exchanges and their federal subsidies,
and the employer responsibility assessment—cannot remain
once the Individual Mandate and Medicaid Expansion are
invalid.  That result follows from the undoubted inability 
of the other major provisions to operate as Congress in-
tended without the Individual Mandate and Medicaid 
Expansion.  Absent the invalid portions, the other major 
provisions could impose enormous risks of unexpected bur- 
dens on patients, the health-care community, and the 
federal budget.  That consequence would be in absolute
conflict with the ACA’s design of “shared responsibility,” 
and would pose a threat to the Nation that Congress did 

background image 56 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

not intend. 

Insurance Regulations and Taxes 

Without the Individual Mandate and Medicaid Expan-

sion, the Affordable Care Act’s insurance regulations and
insurance taxes impose risks on insurance companies and
their customers that this Court cannot measure.  Those 
risks would undermine Congress’ scheme of “shared re-
sponsibility.”  See 26 U. S. C. §4980I (2006 ed., Supp. 
IV) (high-cost insurance plans); 42 U. S. C. §§300gg(a)(1) 
(2006 ed., Supp. IV), 300gg–4(b) (community rating); 
§§300gg–1, 300gg–3, 300gg–4(a) (guaranteed issue);
§300gg–11 (elimination of coverage limits); §300gg–14(a) 
(dependent children up to age 26); ACA §§9010, 10905,
124 Stat. 865, 1017 (excise tax); HCERA §1401, 124 Stat.
1059 (excise tax).

The Court has been informed by distinguished econo-

mists that the Act’s Individual Mandate and Medicaid 
Expansion would each increase revenues to the insurance 
industry by about $350 billion over 10 years; that this
combined figure of $700 billion is necessary to offset the 
approximately $700 billion in new costs to the insurance 
industry imposed by the Act’s insurance regulations and
taxes; and that the new $700-billion burden would other-
wise dwarf the industry’s current profit margin.  See Brief 
for Economists as Amici Curiae in No. 11–393 etc. (Sever-
ability), pp. 9–16, 10a.

If that analysis is correct, the regulations and taxes will

mean higher costs for insurance companies.  Higher costs
may mean higher premiums for consumers, despite the
Act’s goal of “lower[ing] health insurance premiums.”  42 
U. S. C. §18091(2)(F) (2006 ed., Supp. IV).  Higher costs
also could threaten the survival of health-insurance com-
panies, despite the Act’s goal of “effective health insurance
markets.”  §18091(2)(J). 

background image 57 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

The actual cost of the regulations and taxes may be

more or less than predicted.  What is known, however, is 
that severing other provisions from the Individual Man-
date and Medicaid Expansion necessarily would impose 
significant risks and real uncertainties on insurance com-
panies, their customers, all other major actors in the sys-
tem, and the government treasury.  And what also is 
known is this: Unnecessary risks and avoidable uncertain-
ties are hostile to economic progress and fiscal stability 
and thus to the safety and welfare of the Nation and the 
Nation’s freedom.  If those risks and uncertainties are to 
be imposed, it must not be by the Judiciary. 

Reductions in Reimbursements to Hospitals and 

Other Reductions in Medicare Expenditures 

The Affordable Care Act reduces payments by the Fed-

eral Government to hospitals by more than $200 billion 
over 10 years.  See 42 U. S. C. §1395ww(b)(3)(B)(xi)–(xii)
(2006 ed., Supp. IV); §1395ww(q); §1395ww®; §1396r–
4(f)(7).

The concept is straightforward: Near-universal coverage

will reduce uncompensated care, which will increase hos-
pitals’ revenues, which will offset the government’s re- 
ductions in Medicare and Medicaid reimbursements to 
hospitals.  Responsibility will be shared, as burdens and 
benefits balance each other.  This is typical of the whole
dynamic of the Act.

Invalidating the key mechanisms for expanding insur-

ance coverage, such as community rating and the Medi-
caid Expansion, without invalidating the reductions in 
Medicare and Medicaid, distorts the ACA’s design of 
“shared responsibility.”  Some hospitals may be forced to 
raise the cost of care in order to offset the reductions in 
reimbursements, which could raise the cost of insurance 
premiums, in contravention of the Act’s goal of “lower[ing] 

background image 58 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

health insurance premiums.”  42 U. S. C. §18091(2)(F) 
(2006 ed., Supp. IV).  See also §18091(2)(I) (goal of 
“lower[ing] health insurance premiums”); §18091(2)(J) 
(same).  Other hospitals, particularly safety-net hospitals that
serve a large number of uninsured patients, may be forced 
to shut down.  Cf. National Assn. of Public Hospitals, 2009
Annual Survey: Safety Net Hospitals and Health Systems
Fulfill Mission in Uncertain Times 5–6 (Feb. 2011).  Like 
the effect of preserving the insurance regulations and
taxes, the precise degree of risk to hospitals is unknow-
able.  It is not the proper role of the Court, by severing
part of a statute and allowing the rest to stand, to impose 
unknowable risks that Congress could neither measure 
nor predict.  And Congress could not have intended that
result in any event. 

There is a second, independent reason why the reduc-

tions in reimbursements to hospitals and the ACA’s other 
Medicare cuts must be invalidated.  The ACA’s $455 bil-
lion in Medicare and Medicaid savings offset the $434-
billion cost of the Medicaid Expansion.  See CBO Esti-
mate, Table 2 (Mar. 20, 2010). The reductions allowed 
Congress to find that the ACA “will reduce the Federal
deficit between 2010 and 2019” and “will continue to 
reduce budget deficits after 2019.”  ACA §§1563(a)(1), (2), 
124 Stat. 270. 

That finding was critical to the ACA.  The Act’s “shared 

responsibility” concept extends to the federal budget.
Congress chose to offset new federal expenditures with 
budget cuts and tax increases.  That is why the United
States has explained in the course of this litigation that 
“[w]hen Congress passed the ACA, it was careful to ensure
that any increased spending, including on Medicaid, was
offset by other revenue-raising and cost-saving provi-
sions.”  Memorandum in  Support of Government’s Motion
for Summary Judgment in No. 3–10–cv–91, p. 41. 

If the Medicare and Medicaid reductions would no longer 

background image 59 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

be needed to offset the costs of the Medicaid Expansion, 
the reductions would no longer operate in the manner 
Congress intended.  They would lose their justification and 
foundation.  In addition, to preserve them would be “to
eliminate a significant quid pro quo of the legislative com- 
promise” and create a statute Congress did not enact. 
Legal Services Corporation v. Velazquez, 531 U. S. 533, 
561 (2001) (SCALIA,  J., dissenting).  It is no secret that 
cutting Medicare is unpopular; and it is most improbable 
Congress would have done so without at least the assur-
ance that it would render the ACA deficit-neutral.  See 
ACA §§1563(a)(1), (2), 124 Stat. 270. 

Health Insurance Exchanges and Their Federal 

Subsidies 

The ACA requires each State to establish a health-

insurance “exchange.”  Each exchange is a one-stop mar-
ketplace for individuals and small businesses to compare 
community-rated health insurance and purchase the
policy of their choice.  The exchanges cannot operate in the
manner Congress intended if the Individual Mandate, 
Medicaid Expansion, and insurance regulations cannot
remain in force. 

The Act’s design is to allocate billions of federal dollars

to subsidize individuals’ purchases on the exchanges.  In- 
dividuals with incomes between 100 and 400 percent of 
the poverty level receive tax credits to offset the cost of 
insurance to the individual purchaser.  26 U. S. C. §36B 
(2006 ed., Supp. IV); 42 U. S. C. §18071 (2006 ed., Supp.
IV).  By 2019, 20 million of the 24 million people who will 
obtain insurance through an exchange are expected to
receive an average federal subsidy of $6,460 per person.
See CBO, Analysis of the Major Health Care Legislation 
Enacted in March 2010, pp. 18–19 (Mar. 30, 2011).  With-
out the community-rating insurance regulation, however, 

background image 60 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

the average federal subsidy could be much higher; for 
community rating greatly lowers the enormous premiums 
unhealthy individuals would otherwise pay.  Federal 
subsidies would make up much of the difference. 

The result would be an unintended boon to insurance 

companies, an unintended harm to the federal fisc, and 
a corresponding breakdown of the “shared responsibil- 
ity” between the industry and the federal budget that
Congress intended.  Thus, the federal subsidies must be 
invalidated. 

In the absence of federal subsidies to purchasers, insur-

ance companies will have little incentive to sell insurance 
on the exchanges.  Under the ACA’s scheme, few, if any,
individuals would want to buy individual insurance poli-
cies outside of an exchange, because federal subsidies 
would be unavailable outside of an exchange.  Difficulty in 
attracting individuals outside of the exchange would in
turn motivate insurers to enter exchanges, despite the
exchanges’ onerous regulations.  See 42 U. S. C. §18031. 
That system of incentives collapses if the federal subsidies
are invalidated.  Without the federal subsidies, individ- 
uals would lose the main incentive to purchase insurance 
inside the exchanges, and some insurers may be unwilling 
to offer insurance inside of exchanges.  With fewer buyers
and even fewer sellers, the exchanges would not operate
as Congress intended and may not operate at all.

There is a second reason why, if community rating is 

invalidated by the Mandate and Medicaid Expansion’s
invalidity, exchanges cannot be implemented in a manner
consistent with the Act’s design.  A key purpose of an
exchange is to provide a marketplace of insurance options
where prices are standardized regardless of the buy- 
er’s pre-existing conditions.  See ibid.  An individual who 
shops for insurance through an exchange will evaluate 
different insurance products.  The products will offer 
different benefits and prices.  Congress designed the ex-

background image 61 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

changes so the shopper can compare benefits and prices.
But the comparison cannot be made in the way Congress
designed if the prices depend on the shopper’s pre-existing 
health conditions.  The prices would vary from person to 
person.  So without community rating—which prohibits
insurers from basing the price of insurance on pre-existing
conditions—the exchanges cannot operate in the manner 
Congress intended. 

Employer-Responsibility Assessment 

The employer responsibility assessment provides an 

incentive for employers with at least 50 employees to 
provide their employees with health insurance options
that meet minimum criteria.  See 26 U. S. C. §4980H 
(2006 ed., Supp. IV).  Unlike the Individual Mandate, 
the employer-responsibility assessment does not require
employers to provide an insurance option.  Instead, it re-
quires them to make a payment to the Federal Govern-
ment if they do not offer insurance to employees and if
insurance is bought on an exchange by an employee who 
qualifies for the exchange’s federal subsidies.  See ibid

For two reasons, the employer-responsibility assessment 

must be invalidated.  First, the ACA makes a direct link 
between the employer-responsibility assessment and the 
exchanges.  The financial assessment against employers 
occurs only under certain conditions.  One of them is the 
purchase of insurance by an employee on an exchange.
With no exchanges, there are no purchases on the ex-
changes; and with no purchases on the exchanges, there is
nothing to trigger the employer-responsibility assessment.

Second, after the invalidation of burdens on individuals 

(the Individual Mandate), insurers (the insurance regu-
lations and taxes), States (the Medicaid Expansion), the 
Federal Government (the federal subsidies for exchanges
and for the Medicaid Expansion), and hospitals (the reduc-

background image 62 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

tions in reimbursements), the preservation of the employer-
responsibility assessment would upset the ACA’s design 
of “shared responsibility.”  It would leave employers as the
only parties bearing any significant responsibility.  That 
was not the congressional intent. 

The Act’s Minor Provisions 

The next question is whether the invalidation of the

ACA’s major provisions requires the Court to invalidate 
the ACA’s other provisions.  It does. 

The ACA is over 900 pages long.  Its regulations include

requirements ranging from a break time and secluded
place at work for nursing mothers, see 29 U. S. C. §207®(1) 
(2006 ed., Supp. IV), to displays of nutritional content 
at chain restaurants, see 21 U. 

S. 

C. §343(q)(5)(H).

The Act raises billions of dollars in taxes and fees, includ-
ing exactions imposed on high-income taxpayers, see ACA 
§§9015, 10906; HCERA §1402, medical devices, see 26 
U. S. C. §4191 (2006 ed., Supp. IV), and tanning booths, 
see §5000B.  It spends government money on, among other 
things, the study of how to spend less government money.
42 U. S. C. §1315a.  And it includes a number of provisions
that provide benefits to the State of a particular legislator.
For example, §10323, 124 Stat. 954, extends Medicare 
coverage to individuals exposed to asbestos from a mine in 
Libby, Montana.  Another provision, §2006, id., at 284, 
increases Medicaid payments only in Louisiana. 

Such provisions validate the Senate Majority Leader’s

statement, “ ‘I don’t know if there is a senator that doesn’t 
have something in this bill that was important to them. 
. . .  [And] if they don’t have something in it important to 
them, then it doesn’t speak well of them.  That’s what this 
legislation is all about: It’s the art of compromise.’ ”  Pear, 
In Health Bill for Everyone, Provisions for a Few, N. Y. 
Times, Jan. 4, 2010, p. A10 (quoting Sen. Reid).  Often, a 

background image 63 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

minor provision will be the price paid for support of a 
major provision.  So, if the major provision were unconsti-
tutional, Congress would not have passed the minor one.

Without the ACA’s major provisions, many of these

minor provisions will not operate in the manner Congress 
intended.  For example, the tax increases are “Revenue
Offset Provisions” designed to help offset the cost to the 
Federal Government of programs like the Medicaid Ex-
pansion and the exchanges’ federal subsidies.  See Title 
IX, Subtitle A—Revenue Offset Provisions, 124 Stat. 847. 
With the Medicaid Expansion and the exchanges invali-
dated, the tax increases no longer operate to offset costs, 
and they no longer serve the purpose in the Act’s scheme 
of “shared responsibility” that Congress intended. 

Some provisions, such as requiring chain restaurants to

display nutritional content, appear likely to operate as
Congress intended, but they fail the second test for sever-
ability.  There is no reason to believe that Congress would 
have enacted them independently.  The Court has not 
previously had occasion to consider severability in the con- 
text of an omnibus enactment like the ACA, which in-
cludes not only many provisions that are ancillary to its
central provisions but also many that are entirely unre-
lated—hitched on because it was a quick way to get them
passed despite opposition, or because their proponents 
could exact their enactment as the quid pro quo for their 
needed support.  When we are confronted with such a so-
called “Christmas tree,” a law to which many nongermane 
ornaments have been attached, we think the proper rule 
must be that when the tree no longer exists the ornaments 
are superfluous.  We have no reliable basis for knowing 
which pieces of the Act would have passed on their own.  It 
is certain that many of them would not have, and it is not 
a proper function of this Court to guess which.  To sever 
the statute in that manner “ ‘would be to make a new law, 
not to enforce an old one.  This is not part of our duty.’ ”  

background image 64 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

Trade-Mark Cases, 100 U. S., at 99. 

This Court must not impose risks unintended by Con-

gress or produce legislation Congress may have lacked the 
support to enact.  For those reasons, the unconstitution-
ality of both the Individual Mandate and the Medicaid
Expansion requires the invalidation of the Affordable Care
Act’s other provisions. 

*  *  * 

The Court today decides to save a statute Congress did

not write.  It rules that what the statute declares to be a 
requirement with a penalty is instead an option subject 
to a tax.  And it changes the intentionally coercive sanc-
tion of a total cut-off of Medicaid funds to a supposedly
noncoercive cut-off of only the incremental funds that the
Act makes available. 

The Court regards its strained statutory interpretation

as judicial modesty.  It is not.  It amounts instead to a vast 
judicial overreaching.  It creates a debilitated, inoperable 
version of health-care regulation that Congress did not 
enact and the public does not expect.  It makes enactment 
of sensible health-care regulation more difficult, since 
Congress cannot start afresh but must take as its point of 
departure a jumble of now senseless provisions, provisions 
that certain interests favored under the Court’s new de-
sign will struggle to retain.  And it leaves the public and
the States to expend vast sums of money on requirements
that may or may not survive the necessary congressional 
revision. 

The Court’s disposition, invented and atextual as it is,

does not even have the merit of avoiding constitutional
difficulties.  It creates them.  The holding that the Indi-
vidual Mandate is a tax raises a difficult constitutional 
question (what is a direct tax?) that the Court resolves 
with inadequate deliberation.  And the judgment on the 
Medicaid Expansion issue ushers in new federalism con-

background image 65 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., dissenting 

cerns and places an unaccustomed strain upon the Union.
Those States that decline the Medicaid Expansion must 
subsidize, by the federal tax dollars taken from their 
citizens, vast grants to the States that accept the Medicaid
Expansion.  If that destabilizing political dynamic, so
antagonistic to a harmonious Union, is to be introduced at
all, it should be by Congress, not by the Judiciary.

The values that should have determined our course to-

day are caution, minimalism, and the understanding that
the Federal Government is one of limited powers.  But 
the Court’s ruling undermines those values at every turn. 
In the name of restraint, it overreaches.  In the name of 
constitutional avoidance, it creates new constitutional 
questions.  In the name of cooperative federalism, it un-
dermines state sovereignty.

The Constitution, though it dates from the founding of

the Republic, has powerful meaning and vital relevance
to our own times.  The constitutional protections that this 
case involves are protections of structure.  Structural 
protections—notably, the restraints imposed by federalism
and separation of powers—are less romantic and have less 
obvious a connection to personal freedom than the provi-
sions of the Bill of Rights or the Civil War Amendments. 
Hence they tend to be undervalued or even forgotten by 
our citizens.  It should be the responsibility of the Court to
teach otherwise, to remind our people that the Framers 
considered structural protections of freedom the most im- 
portant ones, for which reason they alone were embod-
ied in the original Constitution and not left to later
amendment.  The fragmentation of power produced by the
structure of our Government is central to liberty, and 
when we destroy it, we place liberty at peril.  Today’s
decision should have vindicated, should have taught, this
truth; instead, our judgment today has disregarded it.

For the reasons here stated, we would find the Act in-

valid in its entirety.  We respectfully dissent. 

background image _________________ 

_________________ 

Cite as:  567 U. S. ____ (2012) 

THOMAS, J., dissenting 

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES 

Nos. 11–393, 11–398 and 11–400 

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

BUSINESS, ET AL., PETITIONERS 

11–393 

v. 

KATHLEEN SEBELIUS, SECRETARY OF HEALTH 

AND HUMAN SERVICES, ET AL. 

DEPARTMENT OF HEALTH AND HUMAN 

SERVICES, ET AL., PETITIONERS 

11–398 

v. 

FLORIDA ET AL. 

11–400 

FLORIDA, ET AL., PETITIONERS 

v. 

DEPARTMENT OF HEALTH AND 

HUMAN SERVICES ET AL. 

ON WRITS OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF 

APPEALS FOR THE ELEVENTH CIRCUIT 

[June 28, 2012] 

JUSTICE THOMAS, dissenting. 
I dissent for the reasons stated in our joint opinion, but 

I write separately to say a word about the Commerce 
Clause.  The joint dissent and THE  CHIEF  JUSTICE  cor-
rectly apply our precedents to conclude that the Individual
Mandate is beyond the power granted to Congress un-
der the Commerce Clause and the Necessary and Proper 
Clause.  Under those precedents, Congress may regulate
“economic activity [that] substantially affects interstate
commerce.”  United States v.  Lopez,  514 U. S. 549, 560 
(1995).  I adhere to my view that “the very notion of a 

background image

NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT 

 BUSINESS 

v. SEBELIUS 

THOMAS, J., dissenting 

‘substantial effects’ test under the Commerce Clause is 
inconsistent with the original understanding of Congress’ 
powers and with this Court’s early Commerce Clause 
cases.”  United States v.  Morrison,  529 U. S. 598, 627 
(2000) (THOMAS, J., concurring); see also Lopez, supra, at 
584–602 (THOMAS, J., concurring); Gonzales v. Raich, 545 
U. S. 1, 67–69 (2005) (THOMAS, J., dissenting).  As I have 
explained, the Court’s continued use of that test “has 
encouraged the Federal Government to persist in its view 
that the Commerce Clause has virtually no limits.”  Morri-
son, supra, 
at 627.  The Government’s unprecedented
claim in this suit that it may regulate not only economic 
activity but also inactivity that substantially affects inter-
state commerce is a case in point. 

Document Outline

cb_mirror_public/nfib_vs_sebelius_pdf_files_19757.txt · Last modified: 2025/04/14 20:11 (external edit)

Donate Powered by PHP Valid HTML5 Valid CSS Driven by DokuWiki